Penalizing Precarity

Retirement policy in America is oriented around 401(k) plans and other employer-sponsored savings plans, which together will receive a whopping $1.5 trillion in tax subsidies over the next decade. This Article uncovers a harmful flaw in the policy governing withdrawals made prior to reaching retirement age: an unnoticed gap between the rules governing plan distributions and the rules imposing penalties on employees in certain situations. Employees are generally required to seek approval from their plan administrator to receive a “hardship distribution.” These requests are granted for employees who face an “immediate and heavy financial need,” such as eviction or an unexpected medical expense. However, even with this approval, these distributions are frequently subject to an “early withdrawal penalty” under a separate regime that is not coordinated with the hardship distribution rules.

We document instances of employees who were able to survive financial calamity because of a hardship distribution only to learn that they now face a tax penalty—resulting in another cash crunch. Retirement plans disburse over $16 billion in hardship withdrawals each year, and the funds go to the most financially precarious households—ones that have fewer assets, lower incomes, and are more likely to be Black or Hispanic. Recognizing the existence of this gap also exposes a fundamental flaw in retirement savings policy: under the existing rules, some workers are made worse off by trying to make use of 401(k) plans. This Article introduces several reforms to protect against penalizing financial precarity by integrating hardship distributions with the early withdrawal penalty regime. We also explore broader reforms to effectively reduce financial precarity among lower-income and lower-asset households.

Introduction

Tiffany1The taxpayers described in this Article are based on real taxpayers. The names and certain details featured in these anecdotes have been changed to protect the identities of the taxpayers. “Tiffany” sought our help in February 2024.
arrived at our Volunteer Income Tax Assistance preparation site in Columbia, South Carolina, looking for help filing her tax return.2The Volunteer Income Tax Assistance (VITA) program provides free tax return preparation for lower income. See Free Tax Return Preparation for Qualifying Taxpayers, IRS, https://www.irs.gov/individuals/free-tax-return-preparation-for-qualifying-taxpayers [perma.cc/44HS-PZZF] (last updated Aug. 13, 2024).
She provided multiple W-2 forms3About Form W-2, Wage and Tax Statement, IRS, https://www.irs.gov/forms-pubs/about-form-w-2 [perma.cc/KNH4-ZJWM] (last updated Jan. 29, 2024) (noting that a W-2 must be provided by employers to each person who earns any compensation for services performed as an employee during the year).
from her employment during the year as well as a 1099-R form4About Form 1099-R, Distributions from Pensions, Annuities, Retirement or Profit-Sharing Plans, IRAs, Insurance Contracts, etc., IRS, https://www.irs.gov/forms-pubs/about-form-1099-r [perma.cc/SKZ5-GPYK] (last updated June 5, 2024) (noting that a Form 1099-R must be provided to each person who receives a distribution from a retirement plan during the year).
showing a distribution of around $4,300 from her 401(k) plan.5We use the somewhat colloquial phrase “401(k) plan” throughout to refer to individual account plans provided in accordance with section 401(k) of the Tax Code, as well as accounts and annuities under section 403(b), which mimic 401(k) plans but can be offered by tax-exempt employers. See infra notes 83–86 and accompanying text. As elaborated there, 401(k) plans are one of many flavors of employer-sponsored “defined contribution” retirement plans, which now provide retirement savings to a plurality of American workers. Compare Employment Retirement Income Security Act of 1974 § 3(34), 29 U.S.C. § 1002(34) (ERISA) with I.R.C. § 414(i) (each defining “defined contribution plan” as a plan that “provides for an individual account for each participant and for benefits based solely upon the amount contributed to the participant’s account, and any income . . . which may be allocated to such participant’s account”).
Tiffany explained that she had made the withdrawal because she had fallen behind on her housing payments and was facing eviction; the withdrawal was necessary to keep her and her three young children from becoming homeless. She was able to use money from her account in accordance with the “hardship distribution” rules that allow withdrawals before a taxpayer reaches retirement age.6I.R.C. § 401(k)(2)(B)(i)(IV) (allowing employer contributions to be withdrawn “upon hardship of the employee”); id. § 401(k)(14) (prescribing types of contributions that can be withdrawn as hardship distributions); Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3) (providing rules for hardship distributions).
These rules include a safe harbor that deems eviction an “immediate and heavy financial need,” allowing the plan administrator to pay out funds to prevent eviction.7Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii)(B)(4) (“A distribution is deemed to be made on account of an immediate and heavy financial need of the employee if the distribution is for . . . . [p]ayments necessary to prevent the eviction of the employee from the employee’s principal residence . . . .”).

The 1099-R form Tiffany presented to us included a distribution code of “1,” an inscrutable demarcation.8Code 1 officially designates a withdrawal as “early distribution, no known exception,” language which is sometimes, but not always, reproduced in fine print on the back of an employee’s 1099-R, and which sheds little light on the tax consequences. See IRS, 2024 Instructions for Forms 1099-R and 5498, at 16 tbl.1 (2024) [hereinafter Instructions for 1099-R], https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-pdf/i1099r.pdf [perma.cc/L8XC-YU55].
We explained to Tiffany that this meant that the amount was presumptively subject to a 10 percent early withdrawal penalty tax.9I.R.C. § 72(t)(1).
, There is no exception to this separate penalty for payments made to avoid eviction despite a taxpayer qualifying for the hardship distribution safe harbor. Thus, people like Tiffany, who are already struggling to make ends meet, often get saddled with an extra, unexpected tax bill.10One of the authors has prepared and reviewed hundreds of low-income taxpayers’ returns over the past eight years as a VITA volunteer and has seen the issues and challenges described here regularly. See infra notes 156–159 (describing a representative taxpayer who faced unexpected medical expenses that qualified for a hardship withdrawal but were subject to an early withdrawal penalty due to lack of coordination between the two regimes).
Further, in Tiffany’s case, there was no tax withheld on her distribution. Nearly six months after surviving a near-eviction experience, she would need to pay both income tax and an additional penalty on the funds she used to stave off calamity.

This type of situation is all too common among financially vulnerable Americans, and we have seen it countless times in our Volunteer Income Tax Assistance (VITA) tax preparation program.11Financial stress, vulnerability, and insecurity have been cited in recent years as problems facing an increasing number of Americans. See, e.g., Dana Braga, One-in-Four U.S. Parents Say They’ve Struggled to Afford Food or Housing in the Past Year, Pew Rsch. Ctr. (Dec. 7, 2022), https://www.pewresearch.org/short-reads/2022/12/07/one-in-four-u-s-parents-say-theyve-struggled-to-afford-food-or-housing-in-the-past-year [perma.cc/AH4N-2ML8]. For a discussion on economic insecurity, see infra Part IV.
The 10 percent additional tax was conceived with two primary justifications.12Tax Reform Act of 1986, Pub. L. No. 99-514, 100 Stat. 2085 (Oct. 22, 1986); S. Rep. No. 99-313, at 486–87 (1986) (emphasizing both the deterrent effect of the 10% tax, and the “recapture” of tax benefits intended to support retirement savings).
First, it was conceived as a commitment device to discourage individuals from dipping into retirement savings during their working years (what experts sometimes call “leakage”).13S. Rep. No. 99-313, supra note 12, at 486–87; Peter J. Brady & Steven Bass, IRS, Decoding Retirement: A Detailed Look at Retirement Distributions Reported on Tax Returns 1–2 (2020), https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-soi/20rpdecodingretirement.pdf [perma.cc/LJA6-GL9M].
Second, it was intended to recover tax benefits intended to promote retirement that are not actually used in that way.14S. Rep. No. 99-313, supra note 12, at 486–87; see U.S. Gov’t Accountability Off., GAO-09-715, 401(k) Plans: Policy Changes Could Reduce the Long-term Effects of Leakage on Workers’ Retirement Savings 28–29 (2009), https://www.gao.gov/assets/gao-09-715.pdf [perma.cc/PGG2-QGD7] (re-emphasizing these continuing justifications for the penalty as offered more recently by U.S. Treasury officials).

Not only are these taxpayers ill-positioned to be influenced by the incentive effect of the additional tax (because, like Tiffany, they are often unaware of it before the withdraw funds), but the additional tax is imposed on taxpayers who have not received any tax benefits to be recaptured. This is because the tax benefit of 401(k) plans is the tax-free return on income earned on investments in the account,15See infra note 46 and accompanying text (describing the equivalency of traditional and Roth style 401(k) plans) and note 122 (showing mathematically that a 0% rate on after-tax investment gains is the equivalent of deducting and deferring tax on the initial investment of funds, as explained by William D. Andrews, A Consumption-Type or Cash Flow Personal Income Tax, 87 Harv. L. Rev. 1113 (1974)).
which means that magnitude of the tax benefit that might be recaptured depends on each taxpayers’ marginal tax rate on investment returns.16Taxpayers who make early withdrawals tend to have account balances below ,000 and have held those balances for under three years. See infra notes 113–114 and accompanying text.
Under reasonable assumptions—namely that low-income taxpayers would be subject to the statutory zero percent rate on long-term capital gains—a low-income taxpayer may be worse off for having put money into a 401(k) plan that she later needs to withdraw that is subject to the early withdrawal penalty than if she had simply paid tax on the money initially and invested the after-tax proceeds.17See infra notes 117–124 and accompanying text.

The reality, then, is that the 10 percent additional tax works as a penalty, borne most heavily by poorer Americans who use their retirement savings to survive in times of desperate need.18This Article refers to people and households that are in economically precarious circumstances with a variety of colloquial terms. Throughout, we are particularly focused on what the Department of Treasury refers to as “low and moderate income” households (LMI), which is calculated under guidelines based on either area median income (AMI) or on the Department of Health and Human Service’s Federal Poverty Guidelines (FPG). Coronavirus State and Local Fiscal Recovery Funds, 87 Fed. Reg. 4338, 4345 (Jan. 27, 2022). “[L]ow income” is defined as households with income at or below 185% of FPG levels or at or below 40% of the AMI; moderate income is defined as at or below 300% of the FPG or at or below 65% of the AMI. Id.
Poorer and nonwhite taxpayers who have the smallest retirement account balances are most frequently penalized,19 U.S. Gov’t Accountability Off., GAO-19-179, Retirement Savings: Additional Data and Analysis Could Provide Insights into Early Withdrawals 1516 (2019) [hereinafter 2019 GAO Report], https://www.gao.gov/assets/gao-19-179.pdf [perma.cc/8KPV-9NJP] (finding, among other things, that African American and Hispanic account holders were more likely to make hardship withdrawals in a statistically significant proportion as compared to “White, Asian, or Other” account holders). See infra notes 113–116.
and penalties are also often imposed on people who have experienced layoffs.20See Brady & Bass, supra note 13, at 11; 2019 GAO Report, supra note 19, at 12.
Perversely, these taxpayers are subject to the extra tax because they are in the most precarious financial position during economic shocks.21See infra Section III.A.

Conversely, the early withdrawal penalty is seldom imposed on wealthy households, and the distribution and penalty waiver rules can actually work to their financial benefit.22See infra notes 168–176 and accompanying text.
Perhaps this is because the 10 percent additional tax does work as an incentive for those with more resources; additionally, perhaps, they may not need to use their retirement savings for unexpected pre-retirement expenses. The waiver rules also help these wealthier families build more wealth, as they are able to pay advisors to help them take advantage of several statutory penalty waivers that are largely inaccessible to the poor.23See, e.g., I.R.C. § 72(p)(2) (waiving the penalty for a loan secured by retirement assets, with requirements that make it unlikely anyone living paycheck to paycheck could ever take out such a loan); see infra notes 216–219 and accompanying text.

If Tiffany were a higher-income individual, she could have avoided the 10 percent penalty by taking a loan from her account rather than making a withdrawal.24I.R.C. § 72(p).
But retirement plan loans require repayment to start almost immediately, often through paycheck deductions, which Tiffany could not afford even if she was made aware of the possibility.25See Retirement Topics – Plan Loans, IRS (Aug. 20, 2024), https://www.irs.gov/retirement-plans/plan-participant-employee/retirement-topics-loans [perma.cc/5M55-VQYN]. Loans are required to be paid back by the employee within five years, in equal amounts paid at least quarterly. Although payroll deductions are not required, we understand that employers often prefer payroll deductions as the best approach to prevent their employees from defaulting, which results in the loan being treated as a distribution (subject to early withdrawal penalties). Id.
Similarly, if Tiffany had arranged a series of annuity-type payments in equal amounts over a number of years, her withdrawal would be penalty-free.26I.R.C. §§ 72(t)(2)(D)-(F).
But these alternatives were not options for Tiffany, and they highlight the absurd regressivity of the gap between hardship distribution rules and early withdrawal penalties: Higher-resource people, particularly those with access to financial planners and tax advisors, have myriad ways to use retirement plan assets early and without penalty.27See infra Section III.C.

The federal government is slated to spend over $1.5 trillion on tax subsidies for employer-sponsored defined-contribution retirement plans over the next decade.28 U.S. Dep’t of Treasury, Off. of Tax Analysis, Tax Expenditures (2023), 29 tbl.2b (estimating total expenditures on defined-contribution employer retirement plans of .535 trillion between 2022 and 2032).
Scholars have recognized that these plans largely heap tax subsidies on the already-well-off,29E.g., Michael Doran, The Great American Retirement Fraud, 30 Elder L.J. 265 (2022) (critiquing modifications to retirement account rules over the past quarter century as primarily serving wealthy high-income workers and the investment industry, while leaving middle-class and lower-income people with insufficient resources for retirement).
and recent policy changes have also often been in service to those whose retirements are already relatively secure.30See, e.g., SECURE 2.0 Act of 2022, Division T of the Consolidated Appropriations Act of 2023, Pub. L. No. 117-328. 136 Stat. 5275 (2022) [hereinafter SECURE 2.0 Act] (tweaking various qualified retirement account rules in ways that provided tax savings largely to higher income people, for example adjusting the required minimum distribution (RMD) rules to allow deferral of RMDs to a later age, at an expected revenue cost of .5 billion, while allowing new exceptions to the early withdrawal penalty rules, discussed infra Section II.B, at an expected revenue cost of .6 billion); U.S. Cong., Joint Comm. on Tax’n, Estimated Revenue Effects of H.R. 2617, the “Consolidated Appropriations Act,” as Passed by the Senate (2022), https://www.jct.gov/publications/2022/jcx-21-22 [perma.cc/RPE3-K4JY] (showing that the revenue cost of deferring required distributions, which implies distributions to higher-income people, is much higher than the partial fix to early withdrawal penalties).
This distributionally slanted aspect of defined-contribution plans is a significant deficiency in American retirement policy, particularly as these plans have come to dominate the landscape of employer-provided retirement benefits.31See infra Part I.
Our analysis of the application of hardship distribution rules and early withdrawal penalties reveals insult added to injury: Despite how commonplace financial emergencies are for lower-income Americans, the financial precarity that many Americans experience is not effectively considered in the basic statutory framework that governs defined-contribution retirement plans.

In this Article, we dissect the hardship distribution and early withdrawal rules, showing how together the rules fail the low-income, low-resourced population that most often dips into their limited retirement savings to avert financial disaster.32See infra notes 113–116 and accompanying text.
We uncover a pervasive misperception about hardships and the penalty regime that works to the particular disadvantage of taxpayers who do not have the means to hire a tax expert to assist with tax planning and preparation. Specifically, many people believe that once a taxpayer receives approval from their employer or retirement plan to receive a hardship distribution, the withdrawal will not be subject to any financial penalties. This is wrong.

The hardship distribution terminology and rules are addressed to the legal authority of the retirement plan, acting as a fiduciary to the participants and their beneficiaries, to allow a withdrawal from funds held in trust.3329 U.S.C. § 1104(a).
The early withdrawal penalty regime is a separate, and essentially uncoordinated, set of rules meant to incentivize workers to leave their retirement savings alone. The lack of clarity resulting from the asynchrony of these two regimes undermines the potential preclusive effect of the penalty, as the distinction between hardship distribution policy and early withdrawal policy often seems to be lost on taxpayers until the penalty comes due at tax filing. Further, we found that taxpayers are not alone in misunderstanding the situation—employers and retirement plan administrators seem to think that penalty exceptions apply when, in fact, they do not. Policymakers, too, have failed to grasp that taxpayers can be caught with surprise tax bills.34One secondary issue that we discuss further, infra Section III.C, is the lack of withholding for hardship distributions subject to early withdrawal penalties. As we discuss, infra note 210, a leading government report on the subject is simply wrong about the withholding requirements imposed on plans that approve hardship withdrawals that might be subject to early withdrawal penalties, indicating that withholding is required when in fact it is not.

We introduce reforms to integrate the hardship withdrawal rules with early withdrawal penalty exceptions.35See infra Part III.
If these heretofore separate regimes can be made to match and complement one another, then a taxpayer receiving a hardship distribution would qualify for an exception to the early withdrawal penalty.36See infra Section III.A.
Among other reforms, some of the existing exceptions should be reshaped to benefit workers who lack resources and access to sophisticated financial planning.37See infra Section III.D.
Even in cases where an exception does not apply, we propose ways to administer the distribution so that taxpayers become aware of the financial repercussions before the withdrawal is made.38See infra Section III.C.
We argue these reforms will work to protect financially vulnerable taxpayers and enhance the effectiveness of the penalties as a commitment device, appropriately focused on those who should truly preserve funds for retirement.

To the extent that a category of non-hardship withdrawals persists—that is, withdrawals that are permitted but subject to penalties—we propose that it be identified consistently by alternative terminology.39See infra Section III.B.
We propose “excess withdrawal,” which indicates a withdrawal that is beyond or outside of the penalty-free amount permitted for a hardship withdrawal and does not satisfy other withdrawal requirements.40The “excess” terminology is also meant to connote that the withdrawal is not necessary (i.e., not a result of a hardship). See infra note 204 and accompanying text.
We argue that reforming both regimes and unifying the hardship withdrawal rules with the early withdrawal penalty rules will promote financially secure retirement for the non-wealthy and avoid penalty taxation imposed on those who have no resources to spare.

Additionally, this Article links the problems with the withdrawal penalties to pervasive deficiencies in American retirement security policies.41See infra Part IV.
We make the case that some of the incentives built into the defined-contribution retirement savings paradigm generally, and the penalty waiver rules for early withdrawals specifically, urge lower-income people to act against their own economically rational interests. These existing policies essentially ignore that, in some circumstances, lower-income households rationally prioritize emergency spending needs over retirement savings. In addition to the more modest reforms we propose to the existing early withdrawal rules, real retirement security requires a commitment of public resources to support retirement for the most vulnerable, and furthermore, policies that allow them to be able to save for retirement and have a rainy-day fund for emergencies. In short, we make the case that retirement security requires getting more money with more flexibility into the hands of the poor.

The Article proceeds as follows. Part I surveys the landscape of defined-contribution retirement plans and describes how 401(k) plans came to dominate retirement savings policy.42Throughout, we refer to and focus on “401(k) plans,” although as discussed, for example, in infra notes 85, 96, the hardship distribution and early withdrawal rules apply in almost precisely the same manner to section 403(b) plans as well. Together, 401(k) plans and 403(b) plans hold over 80 percent of assets in employer-based defined-contribution plans. See Retirement Assets Total .4 Trillion in Fourth Quarter 2023, Inv. Co. Inst. (Mar. 14, 2024), https://www.ici.org/statistical-report/ret_23_q4 [perma.cc/V3F3-KS4L].
As discussed further in this first Part, our focus in this Article is on 401(k) plans and their close relative, 403(b) plans. Other employer-sponsored defined-contribution plans have distinctive rules,43For example, the early withdrawal penalty does not apply to section 457(b) plans. See Retirement Topics: Exceptions to Tax on Early Distributions, IRS, https://www.irs.gov/retirement-plans/plan-participant-employee/retirement-topics-exceptions-to-tax-on-early-distributions [perma.cc/2LUJ-34DF] (last updated Aug. 19, 2024).
and individual retirement accounts (often referred to as IRAs) are subject to some of the same penalty rules (although penalty-free withdrawals are permitted with more leniency), but do not suffer from the gap addressed in the Article because there is no employer involved in the administration of the account.44See infra note 97.

Part II describes the gap that exists for 401(k) plans between hardship distribution rules and the early withdrawal penalty rules and exceptions. This Part also discusses the normative goals that undergird these rules and critiques the rules for failing to achieve these goals for low-income taxpayers. Part III proposes fixes to the existing hardship distribution and early withdrawal regimes, in two channels. First, we propose introducing income- and asset-based waivers for the early withdrawal penalty, on the basis that the penalties for low-income and low-resource people do not work as a commitment device, do not effectively recapture misplaced tax benefits, and are distributively unjust. Second, we propose integrating hardship rules with early withdrawal rules and improving communication and clarity on how these rules work in practice so that taxpayers, operating without the benefit of paid advisors, are able to navigate them. Part IV turns to the broader issues raised by our critiques of the defined-contribution retirement plans: namely, how this approach fails to serve taxpayers who do not have and will not have adequate resources to be able to save for retirement. A final Part concludes.

I. 401(k) Plans in Context

In the language of federal income taxation, a “qualified” retirement plan is one that qualifies for tax benefits by way of meeting intricate requirements prescribed by Congress and the Department of Treasury.45See I.R.C. § 4974(c) (defining “qualified retirement plan[s]” subject to the required minimum distribution requirements to include plans subject to § 401(a) as well as § 403 annuities and § 408 individual retirement accounts); id. § 401(a) (providing the essential requirements for a “qualified” plan to receive tax deferral benefits, and prescribing requirements for several categories of qualified retirement plans); id. § 401(k)(2) (prescribing requirements for employer-sponsored savings plans, which allow an employee elect to have contributions held in trust on the employee’s behalf). By contrast, nonqualified plans do not meet all the ERISA requirements and do not qualify for the same tax advantages as qualified plans. See Bruce J. McNeil, Nonqualified Deferred CompensationJ. Deferred Comp., Summer 2007, at 21, 22–23. The tax benefit of these plans is the ability to defer compensation and substitute the corporation’s marginal tax rates for the manager’s marginal tax rates. Michael Doran, The Puzzle of Nonqualified Retirement Pay, 70 Tax L. Rev. 181, 185–93 (2017). Thus, the corporation and the manager can substantially reduce the tax burden on the investment of that compensation. Id. These plans do not require nondiscrimination and can be limited to high-income executives.
Qualified plans allow for tax-free investment returns, either by way of a deduction from gross income in the year of contribution or an exclusion in the year of distribution.46See Doran, supra note 29, at 280–83; Daniel I. Halperin, Interest in Disguise: Taxing the “Time Value of Money, 95 Yale L.J. 506, 519–20 (1986). In addition, if the tax rate at the time of distribution is lower than the tax rate at the time of contribution, the front-end tax savings exceeds the back-end tax. Id.
For “traditional” plans, income taxes are generally only due when funds are distributed from the plan to the employee, so long as the employee has reached retirement age at the time of receipt;47I.R.C. § 402(a).
for “Roth” plans, income taxes are due up front and withdrawals for retirement are not subject to tax.48Id. § 402A(a).
Further, the rules allow employers to deduct currently some amounts they contribute to the plan, even though employees will not receive those amounts until later.49Id. § 404(a).

A century ago, most employees had no retirement benefits whatsoever.50Patrick W. Seburn, Evolution of Employer-Provided Defined Benefit Pensions, Monthly Lab. Rev., Dec. 1991, at 16, 19.
For those who did, the primary vehicle for private retirement savings was a type of qualified retirement plan called a defined-benefit plan—commonly known as a pension.51In 1930 about one-tenth of the workforce, or about 2.7 million workers, was covered by defined-benefit plans. Id. Defined-benefit plans are, by definition, pensions, because the employer is obligated to fund the benefit promised to its employees. See Treas. Reg. § 1.401-1(b)(1)(i) (1977) (“A pension plan within the meaning of section 401(a) is a plan established and maintained by an employer primarily to provide systematically for the payment of definitely determinable benefits to his employees over a period of years, usually for life, after retirement.”). Most, but not all, pension plans are defined-benefit plans. Some defined-contribution plans are technically pensions, such as money purchase pension plans. See Choosing a Retirement Plan: Money Purchase Plan, IRS, https://www.irs.gov/retirement-plans/choosing-a-retirement-plan-money-purchase-plan [perma.cc/CF92-JVFY] (last updated Feb. 29, 2024).
Under the defined-benefit model, the employer funds an annuity that guarantees a certain level of income for the retiree until death.52Seburn, supra note 50, at 18.
These plans began to catch on under the early income tax statutes following the ratification of the Sixteenth Amendment in 1913,53 U.S. Const. amend. XVI.
which allowed corporations to take deductions for contributions made to employee pensions.54See I.R.C. § 234(a)(1). Businesses inferred that the provided deductions for expenses included deferred compensation. Seburn, supra note 50, at 18.
lowering their federal corporate income tax bills.55See Revenue Act of 1921, Pub. L. No. 67-98, § 219(f), 42 Stat. 227, 247. Prior to the statute, this had been an informal practice implemented administratively. Seburn, supra note 50, at 18. Public sector pensions have a longer history dating back to military pensions during the Revolutionary War. Robert L. Clark, Lee A. Craig & Jack W. Wilson, A History of Public Sector Pensions in the United States 2 (2003). By the 1850s large cities began offering pensions to their police and fire departments. Id. at 4. Nonmilitary federal workers were provided with pensions with the enactment of the Federal Employees Retirement Act of 1920. Id. at 5. After 1920 public pension coverage was widespread and outpaced private sector coverage. Id.
However, employees covered under these plans had no guaranteed right to this future income, leaving them vulnerable. Further, these plans were not offered to most employees.56Seburn, supra note 50, at 18.

Retirement security became a more prominent policy concern during the Great Depression, which gave rise to the Social Security Act in 1935.57In 1935 President Roosevelt signed Social Security into law. Social Security Act of 1935, Pub. L. No. 74-271, 49 Stat. 620. This was a government pension system that assured that most workers would at least have some modest income in retirement, based on a calculation that today provides a benefit that is a portion of inflation-adjusted average monthly earnings over up to 35 years of work. See Social Security Benefits Amounts, Soc. Sec. Admin., https://www.ssa.gov/oact/cola/Benefits.html [perma.cc/EF4T-8VZL]. Lower-income workers receive a benefit that is a higher portion of their average earnings (90% at the lowest end), while higher-income workers receive a lower percentage but a higher dollar amount. See id. This serves as an employer/employee funded safety net that is publicly administered.
Around the same time, the National Labor Relations Act empowered labor unions, which then successfully pushed for increased pension benefits and expanded coverage for private sector employees.58Seburn, supra note 50, at 20; see National Labor Relations Act, Pub. L. No. 74-198, 49 Stat. 449 (1935).
World War II fueled further growth of private employer pensions, partly because pensions were exempt from the wage freeze imposed during that time.59Stabilization Act of 1942, Pub. L. No. 77-729, § 10, 56 Stat. 765, 768; see also Fran Hawthorne, A Brief History of American Pensions: The Origins of U.S. Retirement Plans loc. 19 (2013) (NOOK ebook).
In response, employers competed for workers by offering more generous pension benefits.60Id. at 19–20.

Around the same time, Congress increased the top marginal tax rates and introduced special tax deductions for establishing pension plans.61Revenue Act of 1942, Pub. L. No. 753, Ch. 619, §§ 103, 162, 56 Stat. 798, 802, 862; Hawthorne, supra note 59, at loc. 19.
Under these new rules, for the first time, companies were required to include workers other than top executives in pension plans.62Revenue Act of 1942 § 162; Hawthorne, supra note 59, at loc. 19.
These changes, along with increased union pressure, extended coverage further. By the end of 1950, over 10 million Americans, or more than 25 percent of the private-sector workforce, had a pension,63Seburn, supra note 50, at 20.
and 10 years later, about half of the private-sector workforce had one.64Id.
Some scholars consider this period the heyday of employee retirement security because Social Security assured most workers of income until death,65In the 1950s Social Security coverage increased from about 60 percent of civilian workers to over 80 percent. Larry DeWitt, The Development of Social Security in America, 70 Soc. Sec. Bull., no. 3, 2010, at 1, 12.
and increasing numbers of workers enjoyed traditional pensions with generous life-long benefits to supplement Social Security.66See, e.g., Hawthorne, supra note 59, at 33 (“Nevertheless, it’s important to remember that this was the high point.”).

Although pensions dominated the private retirement benefit landscape, employers also made use of defined-contribution plans, often to supplement pensions.6729 U.S.C. § 1002(34); I.R.C. § 414(i) (defining “defined contribution plan”); see Edward A. Zelinsky, The Defined Contribution Paradigm, 114 Yale L.J. 451, 455–56, 471 (2004).
Defined-contribution plans, which first received federal tax subsidies in 1921, provide an individual account balance that accrues to the benefit of an employee at retirement age.68See Revenue Act of 1921, Pub. L. No. 67–98, § 219(f), 42 Stat. 227, 249.
Initially, defined-contribution plans were either profit-sharing or stock-bonus plans in which an employer made a contribution to the plan on behalf of an employee—the employee, however, had no autonomy to decide whether to take the payment in some other form.69Rev. Rul. 56-497, 1956-2 C.B. 284 (approving a CODA under which all employees with three years of service were eligible to participate in the employer’s annual profits); see William L. Sollee, Cash or Deferred Arrangements (Section 401(k)): Legal Issues and Plan Design, 29 Ann. Tax Conf. 75, 75 (1983).
The basic structure gave the employer discretion and flexibility to decide not to make contributions in years in which there were no profits to share. In the 1950s, the IRS approved Cash or Deferred Arrangements (CODAs), a new feature for defined-contribution plans that allowed employers to offer employees a choice as to whether to receive an amount in cash or to have it contributed to a trust as deferred income held on the employee’s behalf.70Sollee, supra note 69, at 78–81.
CODAs were the precursors to the modern 401(k) plans.71Technically, what people colloquially refer to as “401(k) plans” today actually describes the feature of a “profit-sharing or stock bonus plan” (and certain other plans) that allows employers to offer elective deferral, as debuted in CODAs and subsequently permitted by Congress in section 401(k). See I.R.C. § 401(k)(1). Elective deferrals are amounts contributed to a plan by the employer at the employee’s election and which, except to the extent they are designated Roth contributions, are excludable from the employee’s gross income. I.R.C. § 402(g)(3). Elective deferrals include deferrals under 401(k), 403(b), SEP and SIMPLE IRA plans. Id.

Through the 1960s, even as the IRS allowed the expansion of CODAs,72See, e.g., Rev. Rul. 63-180, 1963-2 C.B. 189 (allowing employers to treat elective contributions as employer contributions that were not taxed to participants until distributed).
Congress, the IRS, and the public were increasingly concerned about the lack of regulation of private retirement plans, prompted in particular by the spectacular failures of some pensions. When Studebaker-Packard Corporation notoriously collapsed in 1963, its pension was so poorly funded that thousands of its employees lost some or all of their promised pensions along with their jobs.73See James A. Wooten, “The Most Glorious Story of Failure in the Business”: The Studebaker-Packard Corporation and the Origins of ERISA, 49 Buff. L. Rev. 683, 683–84 (2001).
By the 1970s, calls for pension reform were rising and the IRS became increasingly concerned about defined-contribution plans as well.74See id. (regarding the defined-benefit plan crisis that led to ERISA). Switching course from prior sub-regulatory guidance that embraced CODAs, see supra note 71, in 1972, the IRS proposed regulations that would have switched course, treating funds paid directly into retirement accounts as employee contributions, thus making them taxable immediately. Prop. Treas. Reg. § 1.402(a)-1(a)(1)(i), 37 Fed. Reg. 25938, 25939 (Dec. 6, 1972) (referring to “[a]n amount contributed” to a qualified plan by the employee “if at his individual option such amount was so contributed in return for a reduction in his basic or regular compensation or in lieu of an increase in such compensation”).

Congress responded in 1974 by enacting the Employee Retirement Income Security Act (ERISA). The new law put rules in place that established federal oversight and regulation of employer-sponsored retirement and health care plans, including funding requirements for defined-benefit plans so that employers had to set aside assets to follow through on promises made regarding later pension payments.75ERISA ramped up funding requirements for pensions and required companies to pay insurance premiums to the Pension Benefit Guarantee Corporation (PBGC) even as they continued to bear a substantial amount of risk in administering these plans. Zelinsky, supra note 67, at 477; I.R.C. § 412; ERISA §§ 301-308, 29 U.S.C. §§ 1081-1086. The PBGC is a United States federally chartered corporation created to encourage the continuation and maintenance of voluntary private defined-benefit pension plans, provide timely and uninterrupted payment of pension benefits, and keep pension insurance premiums at the lowest level necessary to carry out its operations. Zelinsky, supra note 67, at 477; Who We Are, Pension Benefit Guar. Corp. (Nov. 17, 2023), https://www.pbgc.gov/about/who-we-are [perma.cc/6CEC-PXVZ]; see also Edward A. Zelinsky, The Origins of the Ownership Society: How the Defined Contribution Paradigm Changed America 37 (2012).
ERISA also temporarily halted IRS plans to severely restrict CODA plans through regulation. Instead, it mandated a study of employee salary reduction features and included provisions that would facilitate individual account plans.76Employee Retirement Income Security Act of 1974, Pub. L. No. 93-406, § 2006, 88 Stat. 829, 992 (barring the issuance of any final salary reduction regulations until January 1, 1977, to give Congress a chance to study the area); ERISA § 404(c), 29 U.S.C. § 1104(c) (allowing defined-contribution plans to delegate investment responsibility to participants and relieve the plan sponsor from investment responsibility). See 29 C.F.R. § 2550.404c-1 (2023) and note that prior to the issuance of this regulation in 1992, employees could not decide and direct how their individual account plan assets were to be invested.
Among other things, the law introduced Individual Retirement Accounts (IRAs), which are not employer-sponsored plans but share some features with the employer-sponsored account plans that would follow.7729 U.S.C. § 1001 et seq., Pub. L. No. 93-406, 88 Stat. 829 (ERISA); I.R.C. § 408; Elizabeth A. Myers, Cong. Rsch. Serv., R46635, Individual Retirement Account (IRA) Ownership: Data and Policy Issues ii (2020); see Kathryn L. Moore, A Closer Look at the IRAs in State Automatic Enrollment IRA Programs, 23 Conn. Ins. L.J. 217, 217–19 (2016); Kathryn J. Kennedy, The Perils of Self-Directed IRAs, 22 Marq. Benefits & Soc. Welfare L. Rev. 1, 6–8 (2020).
The groundwork laid in ERISA led to the enactment of section 401(k) of the Tax Code in 1978, in which Congress blessed the CODA concept by allowing employees to elect to defer income by channeling it into a retirement plan featuring an individual account balance.78Revenue Act of 1978, Pub. L. No. 95-600, § 135, 92 Stat. 2763, 2785–87. For example, ERISA limits to 10 percent the portion of pension plan assets that can consist of stock of the employer, whereas there is no limit on employer stock in defined-contribution plans. Professor Zelinsky notes that this permitted Enron employees to stuff their 401(k)s with Enron stock, to disastrous result. Zelinsky, supra note 67, at 479–80, 483.
In 1981, the Department of Treasury proposed regulations facilitating the use of elective deferrals under section 401(k).79Certain Cash or Deferred Arrangements Under Employee Plans, 46 Fed. Reg. 55544 (proposed Nov. 10, 1981) (to be codified Treas. Reg. pt. 1). The regulations today appear at Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1 (as amended in 2019).
By 1982, several companies like Johnson & Johnson, PepsiCo, and JCPenney were offering plans and nonprofits were offering annuities under section 403(b) that worked in a similar fashion.80See Herbert A. Whitehouse, Toward a More Complete History: Johnson & Johnson’s 401(k) Nursery, EBRI Notes, Dec. 2003, at 2–3; Zelinsky, supra note 67, at 471.

Today, about two-thirds of working families have some sort of retirement savings or pension.81 Fed. Rsrv., Changes in Family Finances from 2019 to 2022, at 7 fig.A (2023), https://www.federalreserve.gov/publications/files/scf23.pdf [perma.cc/AN2Q-7GYN]. According to the Bureau of Labor Statistics, 68 percent of private industry workers have access to retirement benefits through their employers, with 51 percent participating. 68 Percent of Private Industry Workers Had Access to Retirement Plans in 2021, U.S. Bureau of Lab. Stats.: TED: Econ. Daily (Nov. 1, 2021), https://www.bls.gov/opub/ted/2021/68-percent-of-private-industry-workers-had-access-to-retirement-plans-in-2021.htm [perma.cc/7YUC-DHKX]. See generally I.R.C. § 401(a). The number is higher for employees of state and local government—in that group, 92 percent had access and 82 percent participated. U.S. Bureau of Lab. Stats.: TED: Econ. Daily, supra.
Around 13.5 percent of workers have a defined-benefit pension, and around 34.6 percent of workers have assets in an employer-sponsored defined-contribution plan.82Maria G. Hoffman, Mark A. Klee & Briana Sullivan, New Data Reveal Inequality in Retirement Account Ownership, U.S. Census Bureau (Aug. 31, 2022), https://www.census.gov/library/stories/2022/08/who-has-retirement-accounts.html [perma.cc/7GMC-ZF35] (noting that the pension plan percentage includes certain cash balance plans, which define promised benefits in terms of a stated account balance). About 18.2 percent of workers have an individual retirement account, including traditional IRAs and certain “Keogh” plans. Id. Keogh plans are a type of retirement plan for self-employed individuals and small businesses; they can technically be set up as either defined-contribution plans with annual employer contributions of up to ,000, or as defined-benefit pension plans with limits on annual benefits. See I.R.C. § 4974(c); Karen Rubner Grotberg, Comment, There Should Be Parity in Bankruptcy Between Keogh Plans and Other ERISA Plans, 80 Nw. U. L. Rev. 165, 169 (1985); I.R.S. Notice 2023-75 (Nov. 1, 2023).
This broad category includes several related but distinct retirement plans beyond those to which section 401(k) applies, and they are each subject to different particular rules.83E.g., I.R.C. § 457(b) (retirement account style plans available only to employees of state and local governments and certain tax-exempt organizations); id. § 408(p). “Savings Incentive Match Plan for Employees,” or SIMPLE IRA plans, are retirement accounts modeled in some respects after Individual Retirement Accounts, see supra note 76, intended for small businesses and self-employed individuals, that allows employers to provide retirement benefits to their employees. See SIMPLE IRA Plan, IRS, https://www.irs.gov/retirement-plans/plan-sponsor/simple-ira-plan [perma.cc/Q7EN-HSE3] (last updated Dec. 1, 2023); I.R.C. § 408(k) (simplified employee pension (SEP) plans are a type of retirement plan that allow employers, including self-employed individuals, to make tax-deductible contributions to an IRA set up by the employee).
Our analysis focuses on “401(k) plans,” which we refer to as such despite some technical nuance.84See supra note 71.
Although we focus on 401(k) plans, the same rules (and, thus, our same critiques and proposals) apply to annuities and accounts governed by section 403(b), which can be offered by tax-exempt employers and in practice work similarly to 401(k) plans notwithstanding a few minor distinctions that we note along the way.85See I.R.C. § 403(b). These plans are available to employees of certain tax-exempt organizations, public educational institutions, and nonprofit organizations, and they are defined as “qualified retirement plans” under § 4974(c), to which the additional 10 percent tax for early withdrawals applies under § 72(t)(1). Additionally, section 403(b)(11) incorporates language regarding “hardship” distributions that almost precisely replicates the language in section 401(k)(14).
Together, 401(k) plans and 403(b) plans hold $8.7 trillion of assets, which is 82 percent of the total assets held in employer-based defined-contribution plans.86See Retirement Assets Total .4 Trillion in Fourth Quarter 2023, supra note 42. Of the .7 trillion, most (.4 trillion) is held in 401(k) plans, while 403(b) plans hold the remainder (.3 trillion); these numbers are current as of December 2023. Id.

In these plans, employees can decide whether to direct compensation to a retirement account on a pre-tax basis or receive the compensation currently as cash.87Recall that this structure originated in the 1950s CODAs. See supra notes 70–71 and accompanying text.
The retirement benefit to each employee varies based on how much the employee contributes to the account and the account’s investment performance.88The popular story is that a benefits consultant named Theodore Benna came up with a way to take advantage of section 401(k) by, in his telling, divine intervention. See, e.g., Hawthorne, supra note 59, ch. 3, loc. 437; Jeremy Olshan, The Inventor of the 401(k) Says He Created a ‘Monster, MarketWatch (Sept. 26, 2016, 3:20 PM), https://www.marketwatch.com/story/the-inventor-of-the-401k-says-he-created-a-monster-2016-05-16 [perma.cc/RH3E-ANF5]. However, this account has been disputed as being overly simplistic, eliding the contribution of other lawyers and experts. See Whitehouse, supra note 80, at 1–3.
This shifts the investment risk and planning decisions from employers and plan sponsors to individual employees, which leads to employers increasingly offering defined-contribution plans rather than pensions.89Zelinsky, supra note 67, at 471–72, 484.

Although this approach purports to allow employees to control their funds, defined-contribution plans suffer from some notable deficiencies compared to defined-benefit alternatives. The employee’s retirement payout is in the form of a cash balance, which means that, rather than receiving guaranteed payments until death, the retiree can only receive distributions to the extent of their savings in the account. The amount available on retirement does not depend on salary or years of service but, rather, is a product of contribution decisions and the investment performance of the account. This can be difficult for many Americans because they are not investment experts. Saving for retirement can involve complex calculations and, further, saving enough calls for correctly anticipating one’s own death.

Nonetheless, 401(k) plans have been designed with an expectation that individuals can make and stick with long-term commitments, consider the time value of money, evaluate different investment options, and shoulder the burden of significant uncertainty about their investment decisions and their future preferences—all dubious expectations in the real world.90See infra Part IV.

These features contribute to bleak statistics about the extent to which lower-income households make use of any of the retirement accounts detailed above. In general, low-income individuals are less likely to contribute to retirement accounts.91Bradley T. Heim & Ithai Z. Lurie, Taxes, Income, and Retirement Savings: Differences by Permanent and Transitory Income, 32 Contemp. Econ. Pol’y 592, 592 (2014).
Although retirement accounts do increase the wealth of low-income workers,92See, e.g., Eric M. Engen & William G. Gale, The Effects of 401(k) Plans on Household Wealth: Differences Across Earnings Groups 34 (Nat’l Bureau of Econ. Rsch., Working Paper No. 8032, 2000), http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.241237 [perma.cc/YFR5-JDNN] (finding that 401(k) accounts increase wealth among those with low earnings); Victor Chernozhukov & Christian Hansen, The Effects of 401(k) Participation on the Wealth Distribution: An Instrumental Quantile Regression Analysis, 86 Rev. Econ. & Stat. 735, 750 (2004) (finding that 401(k) accounts do increase wealth among those with low assets).
the effects are exceedingly small: According to one estimate, the lowest quintile on the income scale receives 2 percent of the tax benefit, amounting to only $6, while the top income quintile receives 61 percent, averaging $1,838.93Leonard E. Burman, William G. Gale, Matthew Hall & Peter R. Orszag, Distributional Effects of Defined Contribution Plans and Individual Retirement Arrangements, 57 Nat’l Tax J., 671, 678 tbl.1 (2004); see also Heim & Lurie, supra note 91, at 614.
A serious indicator that individual accounts are useless for a large swath of workers is the median retirement account balance for all working-age individuals: zero dollars.94 Jennifer Erin Brown, Joelle Saad-Lessler & Diane Oakley, Nat’l Inst. on Ret. Sec., Retirement in America: Out of Reach for Working Adults? 1 (2018), https://www.nirsonline.org/wp-content/uploads/2018/09/SavingsCrisis_Final.pdf [perma.cc/H32E-SA6Z].
This means more workers than not have no money accrued in their retirement accounts. Further, even those low-income taxpayers who do have funds in a 401(k) account may have no de facto tax benefit even if they do maintain their savings until retirement time, because of the zero percent capital gains bracket for lower-income taxpayers.95See infra notes 117–124 and accompanying text (showing that the tax benefit achieved by elective deferral of income into a 401(k) plan is the equivalent of exempting the yield from tax, i.e., imposing a zero percent rate on investments of after-tax earnings, which under current policy actually is the applicable long-term capital gains rate for lower-income households).

As the next Part describes, those who do have accounts but are struggling to make ends meet can face stiff financial penalties for attempting to save for retirement.

II. The Gap Between Hardship Distributions and
Early Withdrawal Penalties

There are two distinct sets of rules that govern what are called “in-service” distributions from 401(k) plans (i.e., distributions made while an employee is still working or could be).96Again, these rules are also applicable to section 403(b) plans. See supra note 85 and accompanying text.
Each regime is generally designed to ensure that savings in 401(k) plans are protected and preserved for retirement, but the rules work with different targets. First, the distribution rules are addressed to employers and plan administrators by prescribing how plan assets are to be held and protected for the benefit of plan participants.97I.R.C. § 401(k)(14); Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3) (as amended in 1994). Although IRAs and similar non-employer-sponsored retirement accounts share some features with 401(k) plans, they are not subject to the hardship distribution rules described here because there is no employer steward of the deferred compensation, meaning that the owner of the account can remove funds anytime. Thus, although the penalties discussed below apply to IRA withdrawals, they do not suffer the same gap between the hardship distribution rules and the penalties, like 401(k) plans. Hardship withdrawals are possible for defined-benefit plans, but such distributions are rare as plans generally do not allow for them. See id. §§ 72(q)(2), 409(d)(3)(H).
These rules provide the legal authority for the retirement plan, acting as a fiduciary to the participants and their beneficiaries, to allow distributions of funds held in trust.9829 U.S.C. § 1104(a).
Second, the early withdrawal rules impose a 10 percent additional tax on employees for any withdrawal from a 401(k) plan, absent a specific statutory exception.99See infra note 103; infra Section II.C.; see also Economic Recovery Tax Act of 1981, Pub. L. No. 97-34, § 311(b), 95 Stat. 172, 278–79. For the statutory exceptions, see infra Section II.C.

The basic parameters of these rules are instructive as to how these regimes should intersect. Congress made a policy determination that distributions are permissible when an employee dies, becomes disabled, or reaches fifty-nine and a half years old.100I.R.C. §§ 401(k)(2)(B)(i)(I), 72(t)(2)(A)(i)–(iii).
For each of these events, there are parallel rules that facilitate distributions. For the employer, section 401(k) allows funds to be removed from trust in each of these events.101Id. § 401(k)(2)(B)(i)(I).
For the employee, section 72(t) allows funds to be received without penalty for the same set of events.102Id. §§ 72(t)(2)(A)(i)–(iii).
The rules are coordinated so that if the conditions are met for the plan to distribute funds, the employee (or their beneficiaries or estate) can, because of the same conditions, receive the funds without penalty.

Beyond death or disability, “in-service” distributions are discouraged prior to reaching retirement age, as discussed below. Nonetheless, they may be permitted in certain limited circumstances without penalty, and the statutes in these circumstances reflect matching, parallel rules for distributions accompanied exceptions to the early withdrawal penalty tax.103For thoroughness, under different authority than the hardship distribution rules, account holders are permitted to withdraw funds from their accounts in the following circumstances, addressed in I.R.C. § 401(k)(2)(B)(i)(II)–(VI) (exclusive of (IV), which covers hardship distributions), that align with exceptions to the 10 percent penalty: (1) in connection with a separation of service if the employee is fifty-five years of age or older, id. § 72(t)(2)(A)(v); (2) if employer stock is held in the plan and it pays dividends that are distributed to the employee as cash, id. § 72(t)(2)(A)(vi); (3) payments received from the plan as part of a “phased retirement annuity,” which allows for the employee to partially retire (and receive some payments from their retirement account) while continuing to work part time, id. § 72(t)(2)(A)(viii); (4) income from an amount was withheld and deposited in the account but is returned to the account holder before the tax return is due, id. § 72(t)(2)(A)(ix); (5) a payment made pursuant to a “qualified domestic relations order,” i.e., an agreement in connection with a divorce that the former spouse of the employee-account holder is entitled to receive some or all of the account balance, id. § 72(t)(2)(C); (6) in a recent addition, if an account holder is diagnosed with a terminal illness (this rule seems to us to overlap with the existing exception for disability, noted in item (1) above). SECURE 2.0 Act of 2022, Pub. L. No. 117-328, § 326, 136 Stat. 4459, 5359. None of these are considered hardship distributions, and they are authorized under different authority than the hardships discussed in this section.
Congress also deemed that a loan from (or secured by) an employer-sponsored retirement account does not constitute a distribution if the loan is less than $50,000 and is required to be paid back within five years.104I.R.C. § 72(p). Note that ,000 is the highest possible loan amount; for employees with fewer assets in their account, the loan amount is limited to ,000 or up to half of the “present value of the nonforfeitable accrued benefit” in the account. id. § 72(p)(2)(A)(ii).
This rule, thus, permits employers to allow such loans and takes them out of the penalty regime. Thus, there is a narrow, though numerous, set of circumstances in which employees are allowed to take in-service distributions or loans and are not subject to any penalty tax for doing so.

But there is a final category of in-service distributions that is not so well coordinated: “hardship” distributions. This is a subset of the rules, directed at employers and plan administrators, that permits distributions “upon hardship of the employee.”105Id. § 401(k)(2)(B)(i)(IV).
The statute does not define hardship; rather, the exact meaning of hardship is prescribed in regulations and left to some extent to the discretion of the employers, and these distributions rules are not matched in the penalty regime.106See infra notes 126–129 and accompanying text.

Using IRS data and analysis from the Government Accountability Office (GAO) and other sources, Section II.A shows that the taxpayers who fall into the gap—those making hardship withdrawals subject to penalty—are among the most financially precarious. Section II.B goes deeper into the details of each regime and how those living in financial precarity fall into the gap. We explain how and why the hardship distribution rules are constructed the way they are, working through the regulations that provide significant discretion to retirement plans to shape rules for their participants. Further, we explain how and why the early withdrawal penalty waivers do not match with the hardship distribution rules. These waivers are statutory and were enacted by Congress in a series of targeted amendments to the Tax Code that decidedly do not mirror the flexibility provided under the hardship standard.

A. Who Falls into the Gap

The distribution rules and the early withdrawal penalty rules may seem like reasonable approaches to ensure that tax-preferred savings are both protected from illegitimate withdrawals and saved by the employee until retirement. But as applied to hardship distributions, the two sets of policies are mis-calibrated: there is a significant gap in how hardship distribution rules107See infra notes 126–129 and accompanying text.
and early withdrawal penalty rules108I.R.C. § 72(t).
relate to one another. The resulting interaction has received little attention from scholars or policymakers, but based on our experiences assisting low-income taxpayers, we argue that it has troublingly regressive effects in practice.109See infra notes 181–182; see, e.g., Michael Flynn & Craig C. Minko, Personal Foul . . . Roughing the Taxpayer: The IRS’ Triple Penalty on Hardship Distributions, 17 Fordham J. Corp. & Fin. L. 15, 43–49 (2012) (critiquing the penalty as it might apply to a higher income account holder, but not considering distributional disparities).

The scope of the problem is significant. The IRS and GAO estimates suggest that taxpayers receive approximately $16 billion to $18 billion in hardship distributions in a year.110 2019 GAO Report, supra note 19, at 12 (analyzing tax year 2013, the most recent for which data was available at the time); IRS, Publication 4801, Individual Income Tax Returns Line Item Estimates, 2019, at 123 (2021), https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-prior/p4801–2021.pdf [perma.cc/2A6V-M6UD] (showing how in 2019, a total of .4 billion was subject to penalty, producing penalty tax payments of .7 billion).
Those distributions go to around 1.7 million taxpayers each year and, each year, around 1.2 million of those taxpayers are subject to the 10 percent early withdrawal penalty for some or all of their withdrawal.111I.R.C. § 72(q)(2)(A); IRS, Individual Income Tax Returns Line Item Estimates, 2018, at 132 (2020), https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-prior/p4801–2020.pdf [perma.cc/SW5E-6W9E] (finding 1.73 million tax returns reported early withdrawals in 2018); IRS, Individual Income Tax Returns Line Item Estimates, 2019, at 122 (2021), https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-prior/p4801–2021.pdf [perma.cc/2A6V-M6UD] (finding 1.74 million tax returns reported early withdrawals in 2019); IRS, Individual Income Tax Returns Line Item Estimates, 2021, at 142 (2024), https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-pdf/p4801.pdf [perma.cc/FD3D-XT4P] (finding 1.56 million tax returns reported early withdrawals in 2021). 2020 was an outlier, as discussed infra notes 178–181, so we do not include that data here.
The most comprehensive study on the issue found that the median penalized distribution amount for taxpayers younger than age fifty was approximately $3,100—meaning that about half of distributions subject to a penalty were withdrawals of less than that amount.112Brady & Bass, supra note 13, at 13. The study was published in 2019 but based on 2010 figures due to a lag in availability of data. Id. at 1.
In short, taxpayers subject to the penalty withdrew fairly small amounts of money with large resultant tax bills.

The GAO found statistically significant differences within hardship distributions as well. Taxpayers who make withdrawals in the face of hardship are more likely to be African American or Hispanic (versus “White, Asian, or Other”), tend to be less educated (high school degree or less), have larger families (seven or more in a household), and are more likely to be widowed, divorced, or separated (rather than married or never married).113 2019 GAO Report, supra note 19, at 15.
They are also most likely to be low income (with incomes below $25,000) or somewhat low income (with incomes between $25,000 and $50,000) and to have cash reserves below $1,000.114Id. at 16.
Further, they are most likely to have total retirement assets of $5,000 or less.115Id.
That is, their hardship withdrawals are coming from already meager 401(k) plans. Finally, there is a higher incident of hardship withdrawals among account holders with less than three years of investment in their retirement account, compared to employees who have made contributions for longer than three years.116Id.

For those who fall into the gap, the consequences can be significant. Consider a taxpayer who arranges to save $3,000 of her earnings that she can either direct to a 401(k) plan or take as current income and invest independently; assume that in either scenario she can earn 10% annually on the investment, and she is in the 12% tax bracket for ordinary income, which places her in the 0% capital gains bracket.117In 2024, individuals with taxable income below ,025 or married couples with taxable income below about ,050 are in the 12 percent bracket for ordinary income and the zero percent bracket for capital gains. I.R.C. §§ 1(a), (c), (h), (j); Rev. Proc. 2023-34, 2023-48 I.R.B. 1287 (providing inflation-adjusted rate brackets).
If she saves for three years, but then needs to liquidate the investment due to a medical emergency, what is the result? In the 401(k) scenario she would have $3,993 of deferred income and investment returns after three years.118Calculated as: ,000 x (1.103) = ,993.
The full amount would be subject to regular tax and the early withdrawal penalty, assuming no penalty waiver applies.119See infra notes 148–154 and accompanying text (describing the exceedingly narrow the healthcare cost penalty waiver rule that snags many low-income taxpayers who receive hardship distributions).
This would give her a total tax liability of $878, leaving her with $3,115 of after tax proceeds from the initial $3,000 of deferred income.120Calculated as: ,993 x 12% = 9, plus ,993 x 10% = 9.
On the other hand, if she takes the income as cash initially, she would pay an additional $360 in tax liability at the outset.121Calculated as: ,000 x 12% = 0 of tax paid initially, leaving ,640 to invest.
Investing the after-tax amount of $2,640, by the end of the third year she would have $3,514 of assets.122Calculated as: ,640 x (1.103) = ,514.
When she liquidates the investment to pay for her medical expenses, her long-term capital gain of $873 would be tax-free (applying the standard rate brackets),123See supra note 117.
and she would be left with $3,514. Indeed, that is exactly what she would end up with if the early withdrawal penalty did not apply.124Calculated as: ,993 x 12% = 9 tax liability, which leaves ,514. This is an application of the classic proof of the equivalence of deferral and yield exemption. See Andrews, supra note 15, at 1127 (citing E. Cary Brown, Business-Income Taxation and Investment Incentives, in Income Employment and Public Policy: Essays in Honor of Alvin H. Hansen 300–16 (1948)).

All told, the taxpayers who fall into the gap between hardship distribution rules and early withdrawal penalties constitute the most vulnerable account holders. As Americans have felt increasing pain due to inflation and increasing costs of living, hardship withdrawals have increased.125See, e.g., Empowering America’s Financial Journey—2022, Empower (Nov. 14, 2022), https://www.empower.com/the-currency/work/empowering-americas-financial-journey-2022 [perma.cc/K96H-AWQF] (noting that hardship withdrawals rose 24% between November 2021 and 2022); Ann Carrns, Hardship 401(k) Withdrawals, Explained, N.Y. Times (Dec. 16, 2022), https://www.nytimes.com/2022/12/16/your-money/hardship-early-401k-withdrawal-loans.html [perma.cc/LNK9-Z6DY].
Unfortunately, as the example above illustrates, their decision to try to save for retirement may be more costly than if they had avoided 401(k) plan investments entirely.

B. How and Why They Fall

1. Permissive Hardship Distributions

Congress prescribed that distributions from 401(k) plans are permissible “upon hardship of the employee”—hardship exists if the employee has “an immediate and heavy financial need.”126I.R.C. §§ 401(k)(2)(B)(i)(IV), 401(k)(14)(C)(i); Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(i).
Under these regulations, a 401(k) plan is not required to allow hardship distributions. But, if it does, it must provide criteria to determine whether a hardship has occurred and also specify how it determines need and the amount of distribution necessary to meet such need by applying nondiscriminatory, objective standards.127Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(i).
This determination is to be based on “on all the relevant facts and circumstances,” and can include consideration of the needs of the employee’s spouse and dependents.128Id. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii)(A).
As of 2022, Congress now allows that a hardship can be established sufficiently to permit a distribution if an employee can provide “written certification.”129I.R.C. § 401(k)(14)(C).

The regulations specify that a distribution is not necessary unless the participant exhausted other sources to satisfy the need.130Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(iii)(B).
A plan administrator may generally rely on the employee’s representation that he or she is experiencing an immediate and heavy financial need that cannot be relieved from other resources.131Id. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(iii)(B)(2).
However, an administrator cannot rely on an employee’s representation if the employer has actual knowledge that the employee’s need can be relieved through other means.132Id. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(iii)(B)(3).
A plan is allowed to add additional requirements as well.133Id. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(iii)(C).

Certain events are “deemed” to constitute an “immediate and heavy financial need.”134Id. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii)(B).
These include expenses for medical care that would be deductible under section 213(d);135See infra notes 152, 155 and accompanying text (describing taxpayer “Sara” who was subject to the penalty tax under these circumstances).
costs related to the purchase of a home for the employee (but not including mortgage payments); tuition expenses for post-secondary education for the employee’s family; payments to prevent eviction; payments for funeral expenses; and expenses related to a natural disaster or casualty loss damage to the employee’s home.136Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii). These rules apply equally to 403(b) plans. See id. § 1.403(b)-6(d)(2) (“A hardship distribution under this paragraph (d) has the same meaning as a distribution on account of hardship under § 1.401(k)-l(d)(3) and is subject to the rules and restrictions set forth in § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3) (including limiting the amount of a distribution in the case of hardship to the amount necessary to satisfy the hardship).”).
The amount of the distribution cannot be in excess of the amount necessary to satisfy the immediate and heavy financial need.137Id. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(iii)(A).
However, a taxpayer is allowed to withdraw enough to cover all federal, state and local taxes and penalties triggered by the withdrawal, including the 10 percent early withdrawal penalty.138Id.

The existence of the hardship standard shows that policymakers appreciated that some workers may need to dip into their retirement savings before they retire. But in the regulations, policymakers have largely ceded the details to plan administrators; as a result, the rules vary across plans. Indeed, plans are not required to offer hardship withdrawals—each plan has discretion to dictate specific circumstances that constitute a hardship in its governing documents.139See id. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3).

In recent years, the rules restricting hardship withdrawals have been relaxed, starting with the Bipartisan Budget Act of 2018.140See Bipartisan Budget Act of 2018, Pub. L. No. 115-123, §§ 41113–41114, 132 Stat. 64, 161.
Whereas previously individuals were required to stop making contributions to the plan for six months following a hardship distribution, that rule was eliminated to allow employees to keep making modest contributions so as to keep benefitting from an employer match following a hardship.141Treas. Reg. § 1.404(k)-1(d)(3)(iii)(C). This rule had long been criticized as ineffective. See, e.g., Flynn & Minko, supra note 109, at 54.
Additionally, employees were previously required first to take a loan from their plan before making a hardship withdrawal; they no longer need to do so.142See I.R.C. § 401(k)(14)(B) (implementing a legal change, prior to which, in 2018, employees had to exhaust their loan options under their 401(k) plans before seeking hardship withdrawals); Hardship Distributions of Elective Contributions, Qualified Matching Contributions, Qualified Nonelective Contributions, and Earnings, 84 Fed. Reg. 49651, 49652 (Sept. 23, 2019) (to be codified at 26 C.F.R. pt. 1).
Further, participants facing a hardship can now withdraw not only the amounts they themselves previously elected to contribute, which was the prior rule, but also their earnings and certain employer contributions as well.143I.R.C. §§ 401(k)(14)(A)(ii)–(iv). The new rule for 401(k) plans allows for hardship distributions of “QNECs,” which are nonelective contributions that an employer makes for every employee (sometimes used to correct for failed nondiscrimination tests), id. § 401(m)(4)(C), “QMACs,” which are qualified matching contributions, i.e., the employee match which is often also a workaround of sorts related to non-discrimination testing, id. § 401(k)(3)(D)(ii)(I), and profit-sharing contributions made by the employer, id. § 402(e)(3). Congress did not update section 403(b) in parallel to 401(k), so this is one point on which section 403(b) plans are treated differently—they are still only permitted to allow hardship distributions from account funds that are “attributable to contributions.” Id. § 403(b)(11).
These rules go a long way to facilitate hardship withdrawals that previously were not possible, particularly for lower-income people with low account balances. None of these recent rule changes were accompanied by changes to the early withdrawal penalty regime.

Thus, for any hardship distribution described above, if an employer permits a hardship distribution in accordance with plan rules that comply with Department of Treasury regulations governing hardships, then the plan has fulfilled its legal duties as a custodian and fiduciary of the plan assets.144See 29 U.S.C. § 1104.
However, for 401(k) plan account holders, the hardship process is just the first set of regulations that they must confront.

2. Limited Early Withdrawal Penalty Waivers

The early withdrawal penalty constitutes a second category of rules governing 401(k) plans, targeting employees (rather than plan administrators) with economic incentives in the form of an extra 10 percent tax on in-service withdrawals.145See I.R.C. § 72(t).
The penalty regime includes numerous exceptions (also called waivers) that recognize circumstances in which the penalty is not appropriate, notwithstanding Congress’s stated goals of encouraging the preservation of retirement savings and recapturing tax benefits that were intended to promote retirement security.146See id. § 72(t)(2); S. Rep. No. 99-313, supra note 12, at 487, and accompanying text.
These waivers include a few new additions enacted in 2022 as part of the SECURE 2.0 Act.147The SECURE 2.0 Act included penalty waivers for certain victims of domestic abuse and for certain first responders. These limited exceptions fit within our general critique of the early withdrawal penalty waiver rules: that the technical exceptions leave many people on the outside. See, e.g., SECURE 2.0, Pub. L. No. 117-328 § 308, 309, 312, 136 Stat. 5275, 5345–49 (2022).

Problematically, these rules seem to have been conceived independently from the plan rules that govern hardship distributions. Consider medical expenses, which are a major source of financial precarity148See Samuel Estreicher & Clinton G. Wallace, Equitable Health Savings Accounts: Bridging the Left-Right Divide, 56 Harv. J. on Legis. 395, 397 (2019) (detailing statistics showing the plight of many lower income households facing unexpected medical expenses).
and which anecdotally are a frequent cause of early withdrawals, as reported by VITA clinic taxpayers.149E.g., infra notes 156–159 and accompanying text (describing “Sara,” an actual VITA taxpayer in South Carolina who made a withdrawal for emergency medical expenses).
Emergency medical expenses are predetermined via regulations to constitute a hardship that justifies an in-service distribution.150Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii)(B)(1).
There seems to be an accompanying exception to the 10 percent withdrawal penalty.151See I.R.C. § 72(t)(2)(B).
But on close examination, there is a gap between the two rules: The hardship withdrawal safe harbor provided in the regulations allows any medical expense described in Tax Code section 213(d) to constitute a hardship (if the taxpayer does not have an alternative source of funds with which to pay the expense).152Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii)(B)(1).
In contrast, the penalty exception is limited to medical and dental expenses that would qualify for the deduction under section 213.153I.R.C. § 72(t)(2)(B)
This section imposes a significant hurdle: medical expenses are only deductible to the extent that they exceed 7.5 percent of the taxpayer’s Adjusted Gross Income (AGI) for the year.154Id. § 213(a). The deduction under section 213 is only available if the taxpayer itemizes because section 213 expenses are below-the-line deductions; the penalty exception prescribes that the taxpayer does not actually need to receive the itemized deduction in order for the penalty to be waived. Id. § 72(t)(2)(B).

In practice, a taxpayer might get approval for a hardship distribution based on an unexpected or unusually high medical expense as defined in section 213(d),155Medical care expenses include amounts paid “for the diagnosis, cure, mitigation, treatment, or prevention of disease, or for the purpose of affecting any structure or function of the body” along with a few other specified amounts. I.R.C. § 213(d)(1).
but then learn at tax time that some, or all, of the distribution amount is subject to the 10 percent penalty because the medical spending did not exceed the AGI floor and qualify for a deduction under section 213.

For example, if a taxpayer has an adjusted gross income of $45,000 and withdrew $5,475 from her retirement account to pay medical expenses that fall within section 213(d), she would multiply $45,000 by 7.5 percent to find that only expenses exceeding $3,375 can be included as an itemized deduction under section 213. This leaves her with a medical expense deduction of $2,100 ($5,475 minus $3,375). As a result, the first $3,375 of the distribution would be subject to the 10 percent penalty, while $2,100 would be exempt from the penalty, leaving the taxpayer with an almost-certainly-unexpected penalty tax of $337. If her income were $30,000 and she withdrew $2,000 for a medical expense, the penalty tax would apply to the entire amount.

This penalty waiver produces unexpected penalty taxes, not only because of the confusing calculation required, but also because the medical expense safe harbor for hardship withdrawals does not contain similar limitations, a problem that we have encountered repeatedly with actual taxpayers who must pay the penalty tax. For example, Sara,156Details modified to protect taxpayer identities; Sara in particular is representative of many taxpayers we have assisted, as unexpected medical expenses frequently prompt hardship distributions.
another taxpayer we assisted through the VITA program,157See supra note 2.
fell into this gap, with medical expenses that she could not afford without dipping into her 401(k) account—but she did not qualify for any penalty waiver. Sara presented a Form 1099-R showing a distribution of a few thousand dollars from her 401(k) retirement account, which she attributed to a medical emergency. Like Tiffany and so many others, her form showed a distribution code of “1.”158See supra note 8 and accompanying text.
Sara was surprised when we told her she was subject to a penalty tax for the withdrawal, because her employer had allowed the withdrawal once she provided the explanation of her medical need. We determined that, despite the high out-of-pocket costs for her medical issue, she would not qualify for the “medical expense” exception to the early withdrawal penalty.159Sara’s adjusted gross income was high enough that the few thousand dollars she spent on medical expenses was just beyond the deduction threshold—had the amount sufficed, we would have had to investigate whether the expenses qualified under the definition of medical costs provided in § 213. But we did not pry about the nature of the cost, given that she would not qualify for the penalty waiver regardless.
The immediate financial result devastated Sara: The early withdrawal increased her federal income tax liability by almost $900—including nearly $400 from the early withdrawal penalty—moving her from a modest refund to an amount owed. She did not have that much cash available and asked us in desperation to help her set up a payment plan with the IRS.

The medical expense gap is relatively narrow, in that there are hardship distribution rules and penalty waiver rules for medical expenses. Other gaps are much wider. A taxpayer who takes a hardship distribution to prevent eviction or foreclosure,160Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii)(B)(4).
like Tiffany,161See supra notes 1–10 and accompanying text.
does not qualify for a penalty waiver.162See I.R.C. § 72(t)(2).
Similarly, a hardship distribution is permitted for a taxpayer to pay college expenses for a child,163Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii)(B)(3).
and although there is a penalty waiver for these expenses in section 72(t) of the Tax Code, it only applies to IRA account holders.164I.R.C. §§ 72(t)(2)(E), (t)(7).
For the other circumstances that are deemed to constitute immediate and heavy financial need—including withdrawals for home purchases165Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii)(B)(2).
and burial or funeral expenses of a family member,166Id. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii)(B)(5).
there is no penalty waiver for 401(k) plans at all.167See I.R.C. § 72(t)(2).

In contrast, there are penalty waivers for a variety of early distributions that do not constitute hardships and that require complex legal and accounting advice to make use of. For example, 401(k) plans are permitted to allow withdrawals for a series of “substantially equal periodic payments,” sometimes referred to as SEPPs, that are made at least annually for the life or life expectancy of the account holder.168Id. § 401(a)(38).
These SEPPs are also exempt from the 10 percent withdrawal penalty.169Id. § 72(t)(2)(A)(iv).
Thus, these rules allow a person with ample retirement savings to set up regular annuity-style payments from their retirement account beginning before retirement age without penalty. The IRS provides three methods of determining payment amounts that conform with the statute, each of which involves somewhat tricky calculations based on the balance in the account and the life expectancy of the account holder or the account holder along with a beneficiary.170I.R.S. Notice 2022-6, 2022-5 I.R.B. 460 (providing the three calculation methods). The “required minimum distribution” method involves recalculating the withdrawal amount each year based on the account balance and the life expectancy in that year; the “fixed amortization method,” in which a rate of return is calculated for the account using the applicable life expectancy, and based on that calculation an amount is determined that is withdrawn each year to draw the account down to zero in equal payments over the designated period; and the “fixed annuitization method,” which provides a different method for setting a withdrawal amount than remains the same each year going forward. Id. See generally Rev. Rul. 2002-62, 2002-2 C.B. 710 (predecessor to 2022-6, which updated life expectancy tables); I.R.S. Notice 89-25, 1989-1 C.B. 662 (predecessor to both Revenue Rulings which laid out initial rules for periodic annual payments).

The inflexibility of the rules makes this a prime example of the penalty waiver rules catering to the well-resourced, both in substance and practice.171Cf. Brian O’Connell, What Is a Substantially Equal Periodic Payment (SEPP)?, U.S. News (Aug. 3, 2022, 10:13 AM), https://money.usnews.com/money/
retirement/iras/articles/what-is-a-substantially-equal-periodic-payment-sepp
[perma.cc/S2EM-TVL3] (quoting a financial advisor saying that account holders should “never try to do this on your own,” and should talk to a tax advisor because there are a number of pitfalls).
In order to make regular early withdrawals under this rule, the account holder must feel comfortable that their retirement savings are sufficient to cover their normal retirement as well as this extra time. Additionally, the rules lock in the equal payments for five years or until the taxpayer reaches fifty-nine and a half years old,172I.R.C. § 72(t)(4).
which means that the account holder must have other funds available for any additional unexpected financial needs.173See id. § 72(t)(1) (explaining the penalty for random withdrawals made outside the SEPP).
In any event, arranging for payments over time is not a useful option for taxpayers with low retirement account balances, and equal payments over time do not solve acute immediate financial needs faced by lower-income people.174The SECURE 2.0 Act “clarified” some details related to substantially equal periodic payments, providing some additional flexibility but not in a way that would benefit lower-income people. See SECURE 2.0 Act, Pub. L. No. 117-328, § 323, 136 Stat. 4459, 5356-58 (2022).

Although there are many waivers, they remain exceedingly narrow in scope and create a mishmash of ways in which taxpayers must carefully and proactively plan their affairs in order to avoid the 10 percent penalty.175As one practitioner observed, “Numerous exceptions to the penalty exist, but most of them are so narrowly defined that they do not apply to the average taxpayer.” William C. Hood, Periodic Payments Avoid Penalty on Early Retirement Distributions, 76 Prac. Tax Strategies 269, 269 (2006).
Of course, careful planning is not an option for many taxpayers, particularly lower-income taxpayers.176Although this Article is focused on 401(k) plans and not IRAs, see supra note 97, there are some notable distinctions in the penalty waivers, with some waivers available only under IRAs, that exacerbate our distributional concerns regarding the gap for 401(k) plans. For example, distributions received to pay for health insurance premiums during periods of unemployment are subject to penalty waiver for IRA owners, while 401(k) plan account holders cannot have penalties waived. I.R.C. § 72(t)(2)(D) (targeting this exception to “individual retirement plan[s],” as distinct from plans under sections 401 or 403).

C. Recent Modifications

The most recently added exception to the hardship distribution and penalty waiver rules also does the best job of coordinating between the two to address the needs of lower-income workers. Starting in 2024,177This rule applies for tax years beginning after December 31, 2023, SECURE 2.0 Act, Pub. L. No. 117-328, § 115(c), 136 Stat. 4459 (2022), meaning it was not available to help Tiffany even though we were preparing her tax return in 2024. Note that Congress, which frequently enacts tax “incentives” on a retroactive basis, decided that this penalty relief for emergency withdrawals would only be available on a prospective basis. What are Tax Extenders?, Tax Pol’y Ctr., https://www.taxpolicycenter.org/briefing-book/what-are-tax-extenders [perma.cc/MR73-M479] (last updated Jan. 2024).
the new provision allows for one “emergency personal expense distribution” of up to $1,000.178I.R.C. § 72(t)(2)(I) (as amended by SECURE 2.0 Act § 115).
The statute explains, echoing the hardship distribution standard, that a qualifying expense is one borne by the “individual for purposes of meeting unforeseeable or immediate financial needs relating to necessary personal or family emergency expenses.”179Id. § 72(t)(2)(I)(iv).
Importantly, the statute meshes the penalty exception with the hardship distribution standard by providing that the plan administrator can rely on an employee’s own certification that a qualifying immediate financial need has arisen.180SECURE 2.0 Act § 312.

This exception, which was accompanied by a handful of other limited penalty waivers as well,181SECURE 2.0 Act added several other limited exceptions to the 10 percent penalty which could be helpful to low-income taxpayers. These include penalty-free withdrawals: (1) in any amount for certain terminally ill patients, SECURE 2.0 Act § 326(a) (codified as amended in I.R.C. § 72(t)(2)(L)); (2) of up to ,000 for victims of domestic abuse, id. § 314(a) (codified as amended in I.R.C. § 72(t)(2)(K)); and (3) up to ,500 for certain payments relating to long-term care insurance costs, id. § 334(a) (codified as amended in I.R.C. § 401(a)(39)(B)). The three circumstances represent shocks that can undermine economic security in inherently difficult situations. Like other medical expenses, palliative treatment and round-the-clock care are costly and unaffordable to low-income individuals and can easily bankrupt them. See Maureen Milliken, End-of-Life Care and Hospice Costs, Debt.org, https://www.debt.org/medical/hospice-costs [perma.cc/Z9UT-4YW5] (last updated Oct. 19, 2023). Lack of financial control is one of the major reasons why victims of domestic abuse are unable to leave their abusers or why they return to them. About Financial Abuse, Nat’l Network to End Domestic Violence, https://nnedv.org/content/about-financial-abuse [perma.cc/SJ2E-UD42]. These circumstances are especially difficult for those without sufficient resources so to the extent that the penalty could at least lessen some of this burden, it is particularly important.
is clearly oriented toward facilitating penalty-free withdrawals in times of unexpected financial need—but it will still prove insufficient for many low-income workers. The $1,000 penalty-free withdrawal comes with strings attached: An employee who withdraws this amount cannot make any further withdrawals in the three succeeding years, unless or until the employee has “re-paid” the withdrawal by making additional contributions of at least the amount of the initial withdrawal.182I.R.C. § 72(t)(2)(I)(vii).
These limitations are particularly miserly, and in our VITA experience emergency withdrawals often come to a few thousand dollars.

Still, these existing penalty waivers do not tell the full story of hardship distribution and early withdrawal penalty policies. One element of the hastily enacted rule from the COVID-19 emergency legislation in March 2020 provided for expanded distribution options and favorable tax treatment for 2020 withdrawals up to $100,000 distributed from 401(k) plans through December 2020.183CARES Act, Pub. L. No. 116-136, § 2202, 134 Stat. 281, 340 (2020). This included employer retirement plans, such as section 401(k) and 403(b) plans, and IRAs. Id. § 2202(a)(4)(C) (borrowing the I.R.C. § 402(c)(8)(B) definition).
Penalty-free withdrawals were permitted for individuals (and their spouses and dependents) who were either diagnosed with COVID-19 or suffered adverse financial consequences from the pandemic.184Id. §§ 2202(a)(4)(A), 2202(a)(1). As with other withdrawal provisions, plan administrators were not required to allow these distributions. I.R.S. Notice 2020-50 § 2(C), 2020-28 I.R.B. 35. However, if they did allow the distributions, they could rely on the employee’s certification that they qualified. CARES Act § 2202(a)(4)(B).
In addition to the penalty waiver, the regular income tax on these COVID-19 related distributions could be spread out over a three-year period, starting in 2020.185CARES Act § 2202(a)(5)(A).
For example, if a taxpayer received a $90,000 COVID-19 distribution in 2020, she would report $30,000 in income on her federal income tax return for 2020, 2021, and 2022, allowing her to spread the regular income tax bill (i.e., the inclusion of previously deferred income) over time.186She also had the option of including the entire distribution in her income for the year of the distribution. See id.

Congress enacted a special rule to allow taxpayers to avoid all tax liability for COVID-19 withdrawals repaid in full or in part, provided that the repayment was within three years after the date that the distribution was received.187Id. § 2202(a)(3).
Specifically, if the taxpayer repaid a COVID-19 withdrawal, the distribution would be treated as though it were repaid in a direct trustee-to-trustee transfer so that the taxpayer would not owe federal income tax on the distribution.188Id. §§ 2202(a)(3)(B)–(C).
If, for example, a taxpayer received a COVID-19 distribution in 2020, chose to include the distribution amount in income over a three-year period (2020, 2021, and 2022), and chose to repay the full amount to an eligible retirement plan in 2022, she could file amended federal income tax returns for 2020 and 2021 to claim a refund of the tax attributable to the amount of the distribution that she included in income for those years. She would not be required to include any amount in income in 2022.

* * *

Although we object on distributional grounds to some of the penalty waivers more than others, we agree that each may be justifiable viewed in isolation. However, the aggregate effect of these technical rules is a thicket that might create the impression that a taxpayer can avoid paying penalty taxes on hardship distributions. In reality, the rules are quite limited, and the complexity may be difficult or impossible to navigate successfully. In true situations of hardship for low-income people operating on their own, the best option is the most recent addition to the Code: the limited $1,000 penalty-free withdrawal.189See supra notes 177–180 and accompanying text.
However, this is an insufficiently narrow and limited waiver, particularly considering the disconnect between hardship distribution rules and the narrow availability of early withdrawal penalty relief that often draws unsuspecting people to withdraw what they later cannot afford.

III. Bridging the Gap for the Most Financially Precarious

The application of the hardship distribution and early withdrawal penalty rules can be financially devastating for workers living in financial precarity. Tiffany190See supra notes 1–10 and accompanying text.
was fortunate to receive a refund despite the unexpected extra tax bill she faced after her withdrawal to prevent eviction. Still, it was clear that the several hundred dollars of additional cash she might have received in the form of a larger refund would have made a huge difference after the challenging year behind her, and as she worked to support herself and her kids. For other taxpayers, like Sara,191See supra notes 156–159 and accompanying text.
an early withdrawal penalty can move them from receiving a refund to owing money to the federal government—money that they often do not have.

This Part proposes some specific policy responses to eliminate the gap between hardship distribution rules and the imposition of early withdrawal penalties in ways that can benefit taxpayers like Tiffany and Sara. These proposals seek to aid the most financially vulnerable and insecure workers in accessing their retirement savings in times of financial distress by making early withdrawals easier and less costly.

The proposals that follow aim to protect the integrity of the early withdrawal penalty as a commitment device for higher-income savers. The proposals also reflect that the recapture justification may be mistargeted in regard to taxpayers with the lowest incomes and lowest account balances.192See supra notes 95, 118–124 and accompanying text.
Perhaps counterintuitively, we anticipate that policies that reduce the barriers to accessing retirement savings for low-income people could help to increase savings rates at lower-income levels. Workers who are aware of the precarity of their own finances may appreciate a clearly communicated policy and a retirement account that they can contribute to without risking further financial harm. Further, removing the additional tax for some low-income taxpayers eliminates a penalty that can put them in a worse position than they would have been in if they had avoided making 401(k) contributions to begin with.

A. Harmonizing the Two Regimes

First and foremost, the hardship distribution and early withdrawal penalty rules and waivers should be harmonized in a way that can work for taxpayers who do not have access to sophisticated tax advisors. This will address the confusion that we believe pervades in this entire regime: that 401(k) account holders are not aware that permission to receive a hardship distribution does not make them exempt from early withdrawal penalties. This reform would make more hardship distributions qualify under a broader penalty waiver. We propose to do this based on an income or asset test, so that lower-income households, lower-wealth households, or lower-asset 401(k) plan participants could avoid the penalty in any case of hardship.

The most accommodating version of this reform would keep the current hardship standard intact and adjust the penalty waiver rules for qualifying plan participants. If the penalty waiver rules completely aligned with the hardship standard, at least for more financially precarious taxpayers, it would allow taxpayers to withdraw with certainty that they would not face a penalty. We propose to follow part of the model of the emergency withdrawal rule that takes effect in 2024, allowing the recipient to assert a hardship and permitting that assertion to extend to allow a penalty waiver.193See supra notes 177–180 and accompanying text.
As discussed below, this approach might curtail the commitment device effect of the penalty for some and could have a revenue cost for the government. But we suspect it may also facilitate low-income retirement savings by giving some employees comfort that they can make contributions without later suffering consequences of depositing funds in an account out of reach in case of emergency.194See Adi Libson, Confronting the Retirement Savings Problem: Redesigning the Saver’s Credit, 54 Harv. J. on Legis. 207, 232–33 (2017) (underscoring how difficult it can be for low-income earners to commit to long-term savings).
Further, it will eliminate the penalty aspect of the additional 10 percent tax to the extent that the tax can result in taxpayers actually having greater tax liability on their savings in 401(k) plans than they would if they simply invested after-tax earnings in capital assets that would allow them to include long-term capital gain at the zero percent rate.195See supra notes 117–124 and accompanying text.

A key challenge in this reform is defining who qualifies for the more lenient penalty waiver. We propose to create a two-tiered system for early withdrawal penalty waivers based on income, wealth, or plan assets. An income approach might allow for penalty-free hardship withdrawals for any household with income (perhaps for the prior calendar year) that qualifies them as a low-income household according to the low and moderate income (LMI) household guidelines.196See supra note 18 (defining low and moderate income (LMI) households). For example, in Columbia, South Carolina in 2022, a low-income household of four people has an income of ,025 or below and a moderate-income household of four has an income of ,500 or below. Dep’t of Treasury, Tool for Determining Low and Moderate Income Households (2022), https://home.treasury.gov/policy-issues/coronavirus/assistance-for-state-local-and-tribal-governments/state-and-local-fiscal-recovery-funds/eligible-uses [perma.cc/W3P4-J2SK] (spreadsheet linked under “2022 Final Rule” header; income information found under the “SC” tab of the spreadsheet). Another option would be to peg the income threshold to the federal poverty guidelines, for example making the waiver available to all families with income below 400 percent of the poverty level. Id.
Using LMI guidelines ensures the lenient waiver rules vary with family size.197See Dep’t of Treasury, supra note 196 (showing LMI thresholds varying by family size of one to eight members).
Another option would be to coordinate the early withdrawal penalty with the zero percent rate bracket for long-term capital gains, so that a taxpayer who could liquidate a non-401(k) plan investment without tax liability on the gains can avoid the additional 10 percent penalty for hardship withdrawals.198While LMI is based on Adjusted Gross Income (AGI), tax brackets for long-term capital gains are based on taxable income. For head-of-household filers like Tiffany, AGI of ,500 in 2024 would yield taxable income of ,600 (assuming she takes the standard deduction of ,900 under I.R.C. § 63), whereas the zero percent rate bracket cut-off for Tiffany would be ,000. See I.R.C. §§ 1(h), (j)(5); Rev. Proc. 2023-34, 2023-48 I.R.B. 1287 (providing inflation adjusted amounts for the standard deduction and 0% rate bracket); see supra note 117 (discussing the 0% rate bracket for single individuals and married couples filing jointly).

Alternatively, a total wealth approach might hold that, for example, anyone with $50,000 or less in net assets, including 401(k) plan assets and other assets, could withdraw penalty-free for any hardship as currently defined in the Code and regulations.199See supra notes 126–139 (detailing the hardship rules under § 401(k)(14) and voluminous accompanying regulations).
This would be more onerous for the taxpayer because it would require accounting for all property; the IRS might rely on the taxpayer to prepare something like Form 433-A, which the IRS currently uses to collect asset information from taxpayers seeking to pay their tax debts for less than the full amount owed.200 IRS, Form 433-A, Collection Information Statement for Wage Earners and Self-Employed Individuals 2–3 (July 2022), https://www.irs.gov/pub/irs-pdf/f433a.pdf [perma.cc/9A7L-ZC52].

For the sake of simplicity, our preferred approach would be to base the withdrawal rules on total retirement assets so that, regardless of non-retirement assets, a worker with $50,000 or less in total qualified plan assets could withdraw penalty-free in case of hardship. This would be the easiest to administer from the 401(k) plan perspective because it would allow plan administrators to primarily evaluate whether the recipient qualifies for the penalty exception without requiring additional outside information (with an exception for plan participants who have retirement assets in separate plans connected to other employment, although employers could be permitted to allow taxpayers to certify that they do not have other such assets).

Although the standard analysis of this sort of leniency would likely warn of reduced incentives to save, we think it should have the opposite effect given the reality that financially precarious household can, due to the extra 10 percent tax, end up in a worse position than they would if they did not use a 401(k) plan. By lowering the stakes for emergency distributions, this approach would allow lower-income people to set aside assets for retirement even when they recognize that they may need those assets before retirement. This would harmonize savings policy with the reality that low-income people are more likely to face financial shocks that require them to tap into retirement savings. We discuss the need for emergency savings policy in Part IV.

B. Vocabulary and Guidance

Harmonized rules should be augmented by clarified communication. Employees who almost certainly do not have financial or legal advisors assisting them should be made aware of the financial implications of early withdrawals. This communication can take several forms, and we focus on adopting common (and more expressive) vocabulary that would be shared with plan administrators and account holders through better and more plentiful guidance. This is not a particularly burdensome proposal: Plan administrators already have substantial disclosure and notice duties with regard to other types of distributions from 401(k) plans,201See I.R.C. § 402(f) (requiring a “written explanation” of the rules applicable to an “eligible rollover distribution,” which does not include hardship distributions under § 402(c)(4)). In I.R.S. Notice 2009-68, 2009-39 I.R.B. 423 (Sept. 28, 2009), the IRS provided examples of the language that plan administrators can use to communicate with participants regarding rollover distributions. Id. at 427–436.
and the IRS already provides some guidance to plan administrators regarding what to do in the event an employee requests a hardship distribution.202E.g., Do’s and Don’ts of Hardship Distributions, IRS, https://www.irs.gov/retirement-plans/dos-and-donts-of-hardship-distributions [perma.cc/44S7-4UDT] (last updated Aug. 19, 2024).

Anecdotally, we see low-income taxpayers face unexpected penalty tax bills because they believe that receiving approval for a hardship distribution from their plan administrator constitutes IRS sanction of their receipt of the funds. They think that the hardship approval is sufficient to waive the penalty, or more likely, they do not understand that there is an early withdrawal penalty. Without changing any statute, the Department of Treasury can reduce the number of taxpayers who confront this situation by simply changing some terminology in the regulations and other guidance.

We propose that the Treasury amend the hardship distribution regulations203Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3).
to distinguish between qualified hardship distributions, which would not be subject to a penalty, and “excess withdrawals,” which would be penalized.204This proposal introduces the “withdrawal” language into the regulations directed at plan administrators, which we believe will help to make these excess withdrawals distinguishable from standard hardship and other distributions.
Although the regulations currently provide a list of financial emergencies that are deemed to constitute hardships, there is no guidance that we have found that sufficiently explains the distinction between those hardship distributions that subject the recipient to the early withdrawal penalty and those that do not.205Treas. Reg. §§ 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(ii)(B)(1), (6). So, for example, current regulations describe but do not distinguish between distributions for medical expenses as defined in section 213(d) and distributions for repairing damage to a primary residence—the former may be subject to an exception from early withdrawal penalties, while the latter is not. See supra note 154 and accompanying text.
The IRS should instead produce some guidance to indicate what specific types of hardship distributions are not, in whole or in part, subject to the penalty. Guidance targeted to plan administrators should emphasize this distinction. Additionally, the Department of Treasury or Congress should impose some duty on plan administrators to communicate the distinction to plan participants prior to making the distribution so that employees are aware of the potential penalty consequences and can plan accordingly.206Cf. I.R.C. § 402(f); see supra notes 201–202.

C. Withholding Rules

The early withdrawal penalties create problems for low-income households in part because of a timing issue: Taxpayers may withdraw and spend the money as soon as sixteen months before a tax bill comes due.207A taxpayer might make an early withdrawal in January of 2024 and not become fully aware of the consequences until they prepare a tax return to file in April 2025.
This problem is not unique to early withdrawal penalties—the penalty may exacerbate the trouble caused by the regular tax liability that arises from most withdrawals.208This regular tax liability does not attach to Roth accounts since they are funded with after-tax contributions. See supra note 48 and accompanying text.
Indeed, the entire tax withholding regime works to prevent this sort of tax-filing cash crunch in the ordinary course.209See I.R.C. § 3402 (requiring employers to withhold taxes from any payment of wages).
Even some policymakers appear confused about how the withholding rules apply to hardship distributions and early withdrawals: The leading GAO report analyzing these issues misstates the law and indicates that employers must withhold 20 percent for most early withdrawals, which is incorrect.2102019 GAO Report, supra note 19, at 9. The report states that early withdrawals are “subject to federal income tax withholding,” id. at 9 n.29, and that “[e]mployers are required to withhold 20 percent of the amount cashed out to cover anticipated income taxes unless the participant pursues a direct rollover into another qualified plan or IRA,” id. at 9, and cites to I.R.C. § 3405(c)(1)(B). Id. at 9 n.30. That is simply a misreading of the Code section; it does, indeed, impose a 20 percent withholding obligation only for certain rollover distributions, and does not include hardship distributions or early withdrawals. See I.R.C. § 3405(c)(3).
In fact, employers are not required to withhold on hardship distributions, and in our experience, they do not withhold211See IRS, supra note 8 (“Even though you may be using Code 1 in box 7 to designate an early distribution subject to the 10% additional tax specified in section 72(q), (t), or (v), you are not required to withhold that tax.”).
—they do not want to take any responsibility (or, perhaps, blame) for early withdrawal penalties that an employee might face. This is particularly unfortunate given that Congress has expressly permitted that hardship distribution amounts can include additional distributions sufficient to cover the tax liability that will result from the distribution.212Treas. Reg. § 1.401(k)-1(d)(3)(iii)(A).

We propose a default withholding obligation on plans that will cover early withdrawal penalties and at least some regular income tax liability. These rules could follow the existing withholding rules for annuity and lump sum payments of certain deferred income.213I.R.C. § 3405.
The annuity and lump sum rules provide for either 10 percent or 20 percent withholding and allow for the individual recipient to elect out of withholding.214Id. §§ 3405(a)(1)–(2), (b)(1), (c)(1)–(2).
This withholding scheme prompts recipients to confront future tax consequences at the time money is withdrawn, and provides an appropriate solution to prevent a future tax-time cash crunch for many taxpayers.215Of course, for taxpayers who are emptying their retirement savings accounts and need the entire amount withdrawn to address an urgent financial need, withholding could cause short-term problems, which militates in favor of preserving an opt-out.

If the hardship distribution rules applicable to a plan administrator become consistent with the early withdrawal rules, as proposed above, then the plan administrator can more easily be made (more) responsible for withholding the appropriate amounts at the time of distribution. Specifically, if the rules require the plan administrator to communicate whether the recipient of a hardship withdrawal will face an early withdrawal penalty, then the administrator could be required to account for that penalty, as well as income tax liability, by way of withholding at the time of the distribution. This would go a long way toward preventing the additional financial shock that results from unexpected early withdrawal penalties. The general thrust should be more one-on-one help and better use of technology to ensure low-income Americans can anticipate the consequences of withdrawals. Hopefully, this can be done in a fashion that does not result in lengthy, inscrutable written disclosures. We discuss the large administrative burdens that low-income individuals face when accessing government programs below.

D. Low-Income Loans

Loans can offer an alternative to retirement plan withdrawals and can limit the use of predatory products like payday loans. In the absence of a strong government safety net, credit is the do-it-yourself alternative.216See, e.g., Megan Doherty Bea, Mariana Amorim & Terrie Friedline, Public Cash Assistance and Spatial Predation: How State Cash-Transfer Environments Shape Payday Lender Geography, 97 Soc. Serv. Rev. 498, 502–03 (2023).
This can take the form of borrowing from family and friends, but often involves high-interest loans from predatory lenders.217See, e.g., Regina Austin, Of Predatory Lending and the Democratization of Credit: Preserving the Social Safety Net of Informality in Small-Loan Transactions, 53 Am. U. L. Rev. 1217, 1231–43 (2004).
Unfortunately, low-income families struggle to access credit on favorable terms.218See id.
As such, payday loans operate as a “shadow welfare state,” filling gaps left by inadequate cash assistance.219See id. at 1228; Greg Marston & Lynda Shevellar, In the Shadow of the Welfare State: The Role of Payday Lending in Poverty Survival in Australia, 43 J. Soc. Pol’y 155, 155 (2014) (first quoting Robert P. Fairbanks II, How It Works: Recovering Citizens in Post-Welfare Philadelphia (2009); then quoting Marie Gottschalk, The Shadow Welfare State: Labor, Business, and the Politics of Health Care in the United States (2000)); Bea et al., supra note 216, at 502–03.

Many retirement plans allow loans to participants, but loan administration methods—and some of the requirements imposed by Congress—put them beyond the reach of many lower-income households. As a general rule, taking out a loan or using a retirement account balance as collateral for a loan constitutes a distribution and could be subject to the early withdrawal penalty. However, the Tax Code provides a safe harbor for certain loans up to $50,000 such that penalty does not apply.220See supra note 104 and accompanying text. Although, the general rule is that loans are generally treated as distributions to participants, to which the 10 percent penalty would apply, certain loans for ,000 or less that are repaid and meet other requirements are not subject to penalty. I.R.C. § 72(p)(2). These loans cannot exceed the lesser of ,000 or half of the value of the retirement account. I.R.C. § 72(p)(2)(A). Additionally, the loan must be adequately secured and the plan must charge a reasonable rate of interest; sham loans can result in a plan being disqualified in its entirety, thus losing its tax exempt status. 29 U.S.C. § 1108(b)(1); I.R.S., Tech. Adv. Mem. 9701001 (Jan. 3, 1997) (holding plan loans resulted in plan disqualification); I.R.S., Tech. Adv. Mem. 9713002 (Mar. 28, 1997); I.R.S., Tech. Adv. Mem. 9724001 (June 13, 1997); see Tax Consequences of Plan Disqualification, IRS, https://www.irs.gov/retirement-plans/tax-consequences-of-plan-disqualification [perma.cc/C6D5-FSRR] (last updated July 22, 2024).
The statute requires that these loans cannot favor “highly compensated employees” by way of more favorable terms.22129 U.S.C. § 1108(b)(1). See generally I.R.C. § 414(q) (defining highly compensated employees); I.R.S. Notice 2023-75 (providing an inflation-adjusted threshold of 5,000 of compensation to constitute a highly compensated employee).
But the statute also requires that loans must be repaid in equal installments, with payments made at least quarterly.222I.R.C. § 72(p)(2)(C).
Plans generally require reasonable repayment. We learned from conversations with lawyers who advise plans and participants that these reasonable plans typically require payroll deductions in equal amounts over the period of the loan.223 S. Rep. 99-313, supra note 12, at 491 (explaining the requirement of a “reasonable” repayment plan).
This makes the loan option a non-starter for any employee who lives paycheck to paycheck and cannot cover their basic needs if their regular pay is reduced.

We propose that the Department of Treasury develop, through regulations, a low-income loan safe harbor that would facilitate a plan participant borrowing in case of emergency. Rather than requiring payroll deductions, the safe harbor would allow a loan balance to be repaid largely or even solely from employer matching contributions, even if the period for repayment would extend beyond the five-year loan limit. Alternatively, the safe harbor could allow loan repayment on a less constrained schedule: for example, allowing employees to wait to make a lump sum repayment if the employer has a practice of paying bonuses. Finally, plans could allow for deferral of repayment with a straightforward route to convert a loan into a withdrawal that either provides adequate notice of the tax and penalty consequences or qualifies under one of the proposals described above to avoid penalties.

These loan-oriented proposals would help to address the gap between hardship distributions and early withdrawal penalties and would also help with the deficiencies in credit markets for low-income households that scholars and policymakers have previously identified.224For example, Mehrsa Baradaran has proposed reestablishing postal banking, which would allow post offices to accept small deposits again. The prevalence of local post offices would increase accessibility. Mehrsa Baradaran, It’s Time for Postal Banking, 127 Harv. L. Rev. F. 165, 166–72 (2014) (detailing historic support and benefits of postal banking); see also Thomas Herndon & Mark Paul, Roosevelt Inst. & Samuel Dubois Cook Ctr. on Soc. Equity, A Public Banking Option 5 (2018), https://rooseveltinstitute.org/wp-content/uploads/2020/07/RI-Public-Banking-Option-201808.pdf [perma.cc/2VB5-GWQG] (proposing a public banking option).

E. Simplification

Generally, lower-income people will benefit from more lenient, less complex penalty waiver rules. Simplification of the complex existing regime aligns with calls from other scholars urging for reform of other economic security programs to achieve greater simplification, decreased administrative burden, and increased agency efforts to help individuals access benefits.225See George K. Yin, John Karl Sholz, Jonathan Barry Forman & Mark J. Mazur, Improving the Delivery of Benefits to the Working Poor: Proposals to Reform the Earned Income Tax Credit Program, 11 Am. J. Tax Pol’y 225, 261–86 (1994); Jonathan Barry Forman, Simplification for Low-Income Taxpayers: Some Options, 57 Ohio St. L.J. 145, 181–92 (1996); Katherine M. Michelmore & Natasha V. Pilkauskas, The Earned Income Tax Credit, Family Complexity, and Children’s Living Arrangements, Russell Sage Found. J. Soc. Scis., Aug. 2022, at 143, 157–60.
Indeed, the early withdrawal penalty rules, particularly the newly enacted $1,000 emergency safe harbor, are not unique among policies oriented toward lower-income households that have long and deservedly been critiqued for their complex and sometimes contradictory requirements.226See, e.g., Anne L. Alstott, The Earned Income Tax Credit and the Limitations of Tax-Based Welfare Reform, 108 Harv. L. Rev. 533 (1995) (illustrating some of the dilemmas of redistribution through tax-based transfer programs). Researchers have recently broken down the costs of administrative burdens into four categories. See Pamela Herd, Hilary Hoynes, Jamila Michener & Donald Moynihan, Introduction: Administrative Burden as a Mechanism of Inequality in Policy Implementation, Russell Sage Found. J. Soc. Scis., Sept. 2023, at 1, 3–6. Herd et al. identify (1) learning costs, which include the time and effort to learn about programs and ascertain eligibility; (2) compliance costs, which involve providing information and documentation to satisfy agency requirements and demands; (3) psychological costs, which entail the stigma associated with participating in certain government programs and the frustration of dealing and complying with agency demands and (4) redemption costs, which focus on the process of actually obtaining the benefit. Id.
Administrative burdens can reinforce inequality by preventing programs from working as they should and disadvantaging some minority groups.227Herd et al., supra note 226, at 9–10.

Other scholars have suggested opportunities for simplification, which we highlight here, as they may serve as a model for simplification to address the gap identified in this Article. 228For example, Joseph Bankman focused on making the tax filing process easier to facilitate greater take-up of benefits that are part of the tax and transfer system, such as the Earned Income Tax Credit and Child Tax Credit. Joseph Bankman, Using Technology to Simplify Individual Tax Filing, 61 Nat’l Tax J. 773, 780–85 (2008).
Additional communications and information from the government to low-income taxpayers would reduce compliance burdens and could provide opportunities to communicate that a retirement account withdrawal may result in a penalty or in a situation where the taxpayer will owe money instead of receiving a refund. Experience from the expanded Child Tax Credit showed that families who had never filed taxes before required high-volume outreach and hands-on assistance.229 Luisa Godinez-Puig, Aravind Boddupalli, & Livia Mucciolo, Urb. Inst., Lessons Learned from Expanded Child Tax Credit Outreach to Immigrant Communities in Boston 3 (2022), https://www.taxpolicycenter.org/sites/default/files/publication/164300/lessons_learned_from_expanded_child_tax_credit_outreach_to_immigrant_communities_in_boston_1.pdf [perma.cc/SV7G-8BXH].
For immigrant families in particular, it was critically important to communicate in a clear, simple, and repetitive manner.230Id. at 16.
A one-off call or a leaflet was not enough,231See id. at 9.
so more intensive outreach would need to be incorporated into the distribution of these benefits on an annual basis. Relatedly, some have called for the federal government to give credits like the Earned Income Tax Credit to those who appear facially eligible instead of waiting for eligible low-income taxpayers to identify themselves.232Yin et al., supra note 225, at 262–63.

Simplification might preempt some hardship withdrawals that would result in penalties. It could also provide some of the informational infrastructure necessary to identify taxpayers who fall within income limitations, permitting them to make penalty-free withdrawals in accordance with one of the proposals we advance above (for example, helping taxpayers learn that they qualify to take out a low-income loan).233See supra Section III.D.

IV. The Broader Challenge of Financial Precarity

As evidenced by the disconnect in the hardship distribution rules and early withdrawal penalty waivers discussed in this Article, 401(k) plans are an underwhelming tool to help financially precarious workers withstand emergencies.234 Stephanie Chase, Leah Gjertson, & J. Michael Collins, Univ. Wis.-Madison Ctr. for Fin. Sec., Coming Up with Cash in a Pinch: Emergency Savings and Its Alternatives 4 (2011), https://centerforfinancialsecurity.files.wordpress.com/2011/06/2011-coming-up-with-cash-in-a-pinch.pdf [perma.cc/R8N6-JQQY].
The deficiencies we have focused on in the 401(k) hardship distribution and early withdrawal penalty regimes stem from the broader fabric of federal retirement savings policies that do not mesh with many workers’ realities of limited ability to save.235Numerous scholars and commentators have identified economic insecurity as a central problem facing an increasing number of Americans. See, e.g., Jacob S. Hacker, The Great Risk Shift: The Assault On American Jobs, Families, Health Care And Retirement—And How You Can Fight Back 14 (1st ed. 2006); Michael J. Graetz & Ian Shapiro, The Wolf at the Door: The Menace of Economic Insecurity and How to Fight It 9 (2020).
These limitations, in turn, are a consequence of abiding economic insecurity throughout Americans’ working years. This Part considers some deeper structural reforms that might address the challenges of precarity prior to and during retirement in more fundamental respects than the reforms proposed above.

A. The Economic Realities of Lower-Income Workers

Unfortunately, many households, including those in the middle class, live just one unexpected expense away from a major financial hardship,236 Pew Charitable Trusts, How Do Families Cope with Financial Shocks? 3, 10 (2015), https://www.pewtrusts.org/-/media/assets/2015/10/emergency-savings-report-1_artfinal.pdf [perma.cc/S6HF-CT7E].
which is often the event that causes households to seek an early withdrawal from their 401(k) plan.237 Barbara A. Butrica, Sheila R. Zedlewski & Philip Issa, Urb. Inst., Are Early Withdrawals from Retirement Accounts a Problem? 3–4 (2010), https://www.urban.org/sites/default/files/publication/28711/412108-Are-Early-Withdrawals-from-Retirement-Accounts-a-Problem-.PDF [perma.cc/HV8Q-S8X8].
A Pew Charitable Trusts study found that six in ten survey respondents reported some form of financial shock in the past year.238 Pew Charitable Trusts, supra note 236, at 4.
The most common financial shock was a major car repair, but significant numbers of individuals also listed injuries, unemployment, and pay cuts as major hardships.239Id.
For low-income families, the effects of these shocks often linger long after the fact. The households which experienced shocks had lower savings and carried more credit card debt.240Id. at 2, 10.
In one survey, half of the families that experienced shocks in the previous year had not recovered financially at least six months later,241Id. at 7–8.
causing increased financial anxiety among respondents.242Id. at 10–11.
One study from 2011 found that 25 percent of respondents had not saved at all for an emergency.243See Annamaria Lusardi, Daniel Schneider & Peter Tufano, Financially Fragile Households: Evidence and Implications, Brookings Papers on Econ. Activity, Spring 2011, at 83, 83, https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2011/03/2011a_bpea_lusardi.pdf [perma.cc/U3PE-LZ8K].
If faced with an expense of $2,000, almost half of the respondents stated that they would not be able to cover it in a month.244Id. Other, more recent studies have supported this general finding. See, e.g., Joanna Stavins, Unprepared for Financial Shocks: Emergency Savings and Credit Card Debt, 39 Contemp. Econ. Pol’y 59, 59 (2021) (finding 25% of consumers do not have any emergency savings, and nearly half could not cover a ,000 expense within a month).
In short, Americans are woefully unprepared for financial emergencies.

Research suggests that Americans are struggling to stay above water not because of lavish consumption, but because incomes have not kept up with increased costs of living in recent decades.245See Diane Whitmore Schanzenbach, Ryan Nunn, Lauren Bauer & Megan Mumford, Brookings Inst., Where Does All the Money Go: Shifts in Household Spending Over the Past 30 Years 3–4 (2016), https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/2016/08/where_does_all_the_money_go.pdf [perma.cc/54PG-KRKP].
Low-income families have been hit particularly hard because of their sensitivity to rising housing costs.246Id.
By 2021, researchers estimated that lower-income families spent nearly three-quarters of their income on food, transportation, rent, utilities, and cellphone service.247Lisa A. Gennetian, Jordan Conwell & Becca Daniels, How Do Low-Income Families Spend Their Money?, Econofact (Nov. 15, 2021), https://econofact.org/how-do-low-income-families-spend-their-money [perma.cc/U8GX-9E9E].
A report by the Census found that the median low-income household spent 62.7 percent of their total income on rent that year.248Peter J. Mateyka & Jayne Yoo, Share of Income Needed to Pay Rent Increased the Most for Low-Income Households from 2019 to 2021, U.S. Census Bureau (Mar. 2, 2023), https://www.census.gov/library/stories/2023/03/low-incomerenters-spent-larger-share-of-income-on-rent.html [perma.cc/AG2U-QGTC].

People struggling to meet basic needs rationally ignore retirement savings. The poorest Americans are unlikely to even have retirement accounts, as these usually require both stable employment and an employer willing and able to offer such benefits.249See, e.g., Judy T. Lin et al., FINRA Investor Educ. Found., Financial Capability in the United States: Highlights from the FINRA Foundation National Financial Capability Survey, 8 (5th ed., 2022), https://www.finrafoundation.org/sites/finrafoundation/files/NFCSReport-Fifth-Edition-July-2022.pdf [perma.cc/G347-SHDE] (“Eighty-three percent of non-retired respondents with incomes of ,000 or more reported having some kind of retirement account, either employer-based (such as a 401(k) or pension) or independent (such as an IRA), compared to just 18 percent of those in the lowest income group. Among college graduates, more than three-quarters (78 percent) reported having a retirement account, compared to only a third of those with no college.”); U.S. Gov’t Accountability Off., GAO-23-105342, Retirement Account Disparities Have Increased by Income and Persisted by Race Over Time 24 (2023), https://www.gao.gov/assets/gao-23-105342.pdf [perma.cc/CC5U-QYAL] (“The percentage of high-income older households with access to workplace retirement accounts was over three times greater than low-income older households’ access (about 75 percent and 23 percent with access, respectively) . . . .”). The GAO report attributes lack of access to retirement benefits in part to employers’ lack of ability and willingness to offer retirement benefits. Id. at 7.
As such, retirement policy cannot equate to economic security until more is done to allow people to support their basic needs and foster emergency savings without dipping into retirement savings.

We favor two broad policy solutions to tackle the problem of economic precarity and fragility at the bottom end of the wealth distribution: First, we recommend subsidizing emergency savings, which would decrease the use of retirement assets in times of acute need. Second, we recommend increasing more direct retirement subsidies for lower-income households, including enhancing Social Security benefits.

B. Basic Needs and Emergency Savings

Even if an individual or a family is able to take care of their basic needs, that does not mean that they are financially secure. Saving remains exceptionally difficult for LMI households largely because basic needs take up much of their available resources,250E.g., J. Michael Collins & Leah Gjertson, Emergency Savings for Low-Income Consumers, Focus, Spring/Summer 2013, at 12, 15.
although the lack of savings cannot be just explained by income.251 Stephen Brobeck, Consumer Fed’n of Am., Understanding the Emergency Savings Needs of Low- and Moderate-Income Households: A Survey-Based Analysis of Impacts, Causes, and Remedies 18–19 (2008), https://consumerfed.org/wp-content/uploads/2010/08/Emergency_Savings_ Survey_Analysis_Nov_2008.pdf [perma.cc/QU7A-AZGR].
Policymakers’ focus on retirement has the unfortunate effect of overshadowing the more common and pervasive problem of unexpected expenses.252Chase et al., supra note 234, at 1.
Further, most current savings and investment incentives disproportionately inure to the wealthiest taxpayers.253Ezra Levin, Upside Down: The Failure of Federal Tax Policies to Support Emergency Savings, in A Fragile Balance: Emergency Savings and Liquid Resources for Low-Income Consumers 39, 40–45 (J. Michael Collins ed., 2015).
The challenge, as we see it, is to target those with the least resources in ways that do not rely on them having extra resources to expend.

The SECURE 2.0 Act, enacted in 2022, addresses the right targets, but in the wrong way. First, it established “pension-linked” emergency savings accounts.254SECURE 2.0 Act, Pub. L. No. 117-328, § 127(b), 136 Stat. 4459 (2022) (codified as amended in 29 U.S.C. § 1193(a)).
To contribute to a pension-linked emergency savings account, an employee must meet the eligibility criteria established by the plan and not be a highly compensated employee.255Id. (codified as amended in 29 U.S.C. §§ 1193(a)(1), (b)(2)).
Plan sponsors can also opt to automatically enroll participants into the pension-linked emergency savings account with a contribution rate no greater than three percent.256Id. (codified as amended in 29 U.S.C. §§ 1193(a)(2)(B), (d)(2)(A)).
The total amount in a participant’s account is limited by the plan but can be no more than $2,500.257Id. (codified as amended in 29 U.S.C. § 1193(d)(1)(A)).
Based on our experiences with taxpayers of very modest means routinely withdrawing their entire $3,000 or $4,000 401(k) plan balances, $2,500 is inadequate and further it relies on employees being able to set that amount aside. Second, the SECURE 2.0 Act changes the existing retirement Saver’s Credit from a nonrefundable tax credit against taxes owed to a matching contribution, regardless of the individual’s tax obligation.258SECURE 2.0 Act § 103(a) (codified as amended in I.R.C. § 6433(a)(1)). Effective in 2002, the Saver’s Credit currently provides a credit of 10 to 50 percent of savings, depending on income and filing status. I.R.C. § 25B. Many low-income taxpayers are not able to take advantage because they do not have enough income. Brendan McDermott, Cong. Rsch. Serv., IF11159, The Retirement Savings Contribution Credit and the Saver’s Match 1 (2023).
These changes, which take effect in 2027,259Id. (codified as amended in I.R.C. § 6433(f)).
will make the Saver’s Credit more generous and attractive and should increase knowledge of the credit’s existence.260For criticisms of the existing Saver’s Credit along these margins, see Gary Koenig & Robert Harvey, Utilization of the Saver’s Credit: An Analysis of the First Year, 58 Nat’l Tax J. 787, 805 (2005); Heim & Lurie, supra note 91, at 613–14; and Doran, supra note 29, at 304.
Unfortunately, the matching scheme still fails to overcome the problem of lower-income individuals lacking sufficient resources to deposit in long-term savings, as lower-income families will still be required give up crucial liquidity in order to qualify for any assistance.261See Libson, supra note 194, at 232.

Thus, both SECURE 2.0 Act reforms provide benefits that mostly require people to be able to save beyond their basic needs. But this puts the cart before the horse: Research shows that low-income recipients of extra cash, primarily today accomplished through the Earned Income Tax Credit (EITC),262I.R.C. § 32.
first use that cash to cover basic needs, but in turn these transfers will increase savings, promote individual autonomy and respect for the poor, and contribute to the overall well-being of the family, with especially pronounced benefits for children.263See Austin Nichols & Jesse Rothstein, The Earned Income Tax Credit, in Economics of Means-Tested Transfer Programs in the United States, Vol. 1, at 137,180–87 (Robert A. Moffitt ed., 2016).
Importantly, by eventually increasing savings, these transfers allow some individuals to save and withstand future financial shocks.264See id.
These concerns have given rise to “universal basic income” proposals,265See, e.g., Philip Alston, Universal Basic Income as a Social Rights-Based Antidote to Growing Economic Insecurity, in The Future of Economic and Social Rights 377 (Katharine G. Young ed., 2019); Louise Haagh, The Case for Universal Basic Income (2019).
as well as arguments in favor of a universal child allowance that would reach all children, especially the most vulnerable.266H. Luke Shaefer et al., A Universal Child Allowance: A Plan to Reduce Poverty and Income Instability Among Children in the United States, RSF: The Russell Sage Found. J. Soc. Sci., Feb. 2018, at 22, 24.
This line of thought supports expanding the EITC, as a way to use existing policy infrastructure to put more money in the pockets of the most vulnerable households.267For example, one proposal would use an EITC-like refundable tax credit to fund Individual Development Accounts that would help lower-income households to accrue wealth that could then be used to buy a home, start a small business, or fund an education. Michael Sherraden, Assets and the Poor: A New American Welfare Policy 220 (Routledge 2015) (1991).

C. Strengthening Social Security

Returning to retirement, how might be existing subsidies be structured in a more cohesive fashion, without heaping more benefits on affluent and wealthy Americans? Our best answer is Social Security. Almost 90 percent of Americans sixty-five or older receive Social Security income.268 Paul N. Van de Water & Arloc Sherman, Ctr. On Budget & Pol’y Priorities, Social Security Keeps 21 Million Americans out of Poverty: A State-By-State Analysis 1 (2012), https://www.cbpp.org/sites/default/files/atoms/files/10-16-12ss.pdf [perma.cc/QVG8-KBUA].
Without Social Security, almost 40 percent of adults over sixty-five would fall below the poverty line; Social Security has kept this number around 10 percent269Id.
and it accounts for a sizeable decline in elderly poverty since the middle of the twentieth century.270Bruce D. Meyer & Derek Wu, The Poverty Reduction of Social Security and Means-Tested Transfers, 71 ILR Rev.: J. Work & Pol’y 1106, 1116–18 (2018).
Social Security also has strong downstream effects because Social Security recipients help their entire families by reducing dependence and adding income to the larger family unit.271See, e.g., Lutz Leisering, Extending Social Security to the Excluded, 9 Global Soc. Pol’y 246, 252 (2009); Ctr. for Glob. Pol’y Sols., Overlooked but Not Forgotten: Social Security Lifts Millions More Kids Out of Poverty 5 (2016).

Social Security is a form of forced savings. The U.S. government collects payroll taxes to fund Social Security and Medicare, and the program is made progressive by distributing benefits through a formula that favors low-income workers.272Martha N. Ozawa & Hong-Sik Yoon, Social Security and SSI as Safety Nets for the Elderly Poor, J. Aging & Soc. Pol’y, 2002, at 1–3.
Additionally, while Social Security does not exempt low-income taxpayers from payroll taxes, one of the main justifications for the enactment of the EITC was to reimburse low-income individuals for their payroll taxes.273See Joint Comm. on Tax’n, 95th Cong., JCS-7-79, General Explanation of the Revenue Act of 1978, at 51 (Comm. Print 1979) (explaining that the EITC was made permanent because “Congress believed that the earned income credit is an effective way to provide work incentives and relief from income and Social Security taxes to low-income families who might otherwise need large welfare payments”).
In effect, the government recognized Social Security will need to fund the entire retirement of some individuals, even as the lowest earners continue to make at least nominal contributions via payroll taxes.274See Bernard M.S. Van Praag & Peter A.B. Konijn, Solidarity and Social Security, Challenge, July/Aug. 1983, at 54, 54 (discussing solidarity and the importance of groups not being able to opt out of social security programs).

Perennial (and not popular enough to be enacted) reform proposals for Social Security include “lifting the cap on taxable wages, compressing benefits for the highest-income individuals, increasing the amount employers and employees pay into Social Security . . . , and bringing all state and local workers into the system.”275 Ctr. for Glob. Pol’y Sols., supra note 271, at 23–24.
Professor Michael Doran proposed a more thorough overhaul that would include curtailing subsidies for higher-income workers, while leaving the status quo in place for middle-income workers, and converting various indirect retirement tax subsidies into direct government-funded enhancements to Social Security.276Doran, supra note 29, at 346–47.
This would radically change the structure of the retirement account incentive system. Other ambitious proposals that present robust improvements over the status quo abound as well.277See, e.g., Pamela Herd, Melissa Favreault, Madonna Harrington Meyer & Timothy M. Smeeding, A Targeted Minimum Benefit Plan: A New Proposal to Reduce Poverty Among Older Social Security Recipients, RSF: The Russell Sage Found. J. Soc. Sci., Feb. 2018, at 74.; Lorie Konish, This Bill Aims to Keep Social Security Beneficiaries out of Poverty. Here’s Where Efforts to Improve the Program Stand, CNBC (Aug. 20, 2021, 4:21 PM), https://www.cnbc.com/2021/08/19/bill-in-congress-aims-to-keep-social-security-beneficiaries-out-of-poverty.html [perma.cc/2EKV-LREG]; Social Security Enhancement and Protection Act of 2023, H.R.671, 118th Cong. (2023); Supplemental Security Income Restoration Act of 2021, H.R. 3763, 117th Cong. (2021); Social Security 2100 Act, H.R. 4583, 118th Cong. (2023).

* * *

The ideas discussed above that address retirement and income security as well as poverty policy show that the problems we confront in this Article cannot be fixed simply by tweaking the rules around 401(k) plan early withdrawals. Rather, economic insecurity that is exacerbated by unexpected early withdrawal penalties is the same insecurity that regularly impinges on workers ability to provide for their basic needs, leaves them with limited savings for emergencies, and ultimately results in income insecurity during retirement. Thus, the circumstances caused by the combination of hardship distribution rules and early withdrawal penalty waivers serve as canaries in the proverbial coal mine of deeper challenges related to economic insecurity.

Conclusion

This Article identifies the gap between hardship distributions and early withdrawal penalties, a problem that we have seen harm financially precarious taxpayers time and again. A scheme of economic incentives that does not successfully communicate the financial consequences ex ante is failed policy. Even worse, the hardship distribution and early withdrawal regimes sometimes impose economic incentives to counteract rational decision making—that is, introducing a penalty tax for people who appropriately use limited resources to tend to immediate and urgent financial needs. The early withdrawal penalty regime sometimes leaves taxpayers worse off than they would have been if they had not used a 401(k) plan to save for retirement. This problem is exacerbated by the unexpected nature of tax bills that arise even despite a taxpayer receiving approval for a hardship distribution. Serious life challenges, like the threat of eviction and unexpected out-of-pocket medical expenses, should not result in additional taxes that have the effect of penalizing employees for having put money into their 401(k) plan. Taxpayers like Tiffany and Sara need and deserve a more transparent system that is easier to navigate. Their financial precarity resulted in each of them—and millions of others in similar situations—facing steep, unexpected tax bills shortly after surviving a time of acute financial need.

This Article proposes solutions to address the gap. We propose changes to early withdrawal penalty regime to more effectively account for the realities of lower-income workers trying to save for emergencies and for retirement, integrating the hardship distribution standard with penalty waiver rules. We propose new IRS guidance to better communicate to how the hardship distribution and early withdrawal penalty regimes interact for some employees. And we suggest additional changes to the Tax Code, particularly in the form of loans secured by even small amounts of retirement savings, that are accessible to low-income workers and thus can help employees use even limited retirement savings to their advantage in times of need, instead of penalizing them into worse financial trouble.

The gap this Article is focused on reflects a retirement security policy that at best misunderstands and at worst undermines the needs of some of the least-well-off Americans. The problem of penalizing precarity in the case of 401(k) plan hardship distributions is part of a broader array of policies that do not adequately meet the ongoing needs of many working Americans, and reforms—small and large—are urgently needed.


*Assistant Professor of Business Law and Ethics, Kelley School of Business, Indiana University— Bloomington.

** Professor of Law, Joseph F. Rice School of Law, University of South Carolina. For helpful comments and discussion, the authors thank Jordan Barry, Michael Doran, members of the Covington & Burling LLP Employee Benefits and Executive Compensation group, as well as participants in the Association of Midcareer Tax Professors 2022 meeting at University of North Carolina School of Law, the 2022 Critical Tax Conference, the Big Ten & Friends Workshop, the 2022 Junior Tax Scholars conference, the University of South Carolina Rice School of Law Junior Faculty Workshop, the Pepperdine Caruso School of Law Tax Policy Workshop, the Georgetown University Law Center Tax Law & Public Finance Workshop, and the UC Law SF Center on Tax Law Speaker Series. We also thank Rich Sheedy for research assistance and Ashley Alvarado and Vanessa McQuinn for their editing assistance. All errors are our own.